Government bailouts and market discipline

The speech and Bulletin put out by the Reserve Bank yesterday made much of the importance of market discipline in the financial sector.  The two documents have slightly different lists of conditions which the respective authors think make it more likely that market discipline will be effective, but a common element is “market participants [must] have incentives to monitor financial institutions”.  Toby Fiennes argues that in the New Zealand context:

“some aspects of the regulatory framework, such as Open Bank Resolution (OBR) and no deposit insurance, reinforce these incentives.”

and O’Connor-Close and Austin, in the Bulletin, add in

“nor is there any policyholder protection scheme for insurance firm customers.”

This has been a longstanding view held by the Reserve Bank.  I’ve long thought it was wrong.

Of course, if you were confident that, were a bank to fail in which you were holding deposits or other interest-bearing securities, you would lose money, and no one would bail you out, you would have quite a strong incentive to pay attention to the health of any institution in which you had a reasonable amount of money, and (to economise on monitoring costs) to hold  your money, as far as possible, with those institutions generally regarded as safest.

Same goes for insurance.  If you had your house insurance with an insurance company, and no one would bail you or it out if the company failed, you’d have quite an incentive to insure with companies that would prove resilient through the worst of shocks.

In the case of banks, OBR is designed to make it more technically feasible for political leaders to let major banks fail.  In that model any losses  (mostly) fall on the creditors, and yet the failed bank can quickly re-open, keeping the day-to-day flow of transactions and routine business credit operational.  It is technically elegant system.  But whether or not it is ever used is not up to the Reserve Bank.  That is matter for whoever is Minister of Finance at the time –  and no doubt the Prime Minister of the day too.

Suppose a big bank is on the brink of failure.  Purely illustrative, let’s assume that one day some years hence the ANZ boards in New Zealand and Australia approach the respective governments and regulators, announcing “we are bust”.

Perhaps the Reserve Bank will favour adopting OBR for the New Zealand subsidiary (since the parent is also failing they can’t get the parent to stump up more capital to solve the problem that way).    But why would the Minister of Finance agree?

First, Australia doesn’t have a system like OBR and no one I’m aware of thinks it is remotely likely that an Australia government would simply let one of their big banks fail.  But in the very unlikely event they did, not only is there a statutory preference for Australian depositors over other creditors, but Australia has a deposit insurance scheme.

I’m not sure of the precise numbers, but as ANZ is our largest bank, perhaps a third of all New Zealanders will have deposits at ANZ.

So, if the New Zealand Minister of Finance is considering using OBR he has to weigh up:

  • the headlines, in which ANZ depositors in Australia would be protected, but ANZ depositors in New Zealand would immediately lose a large chunk of their money (an OBR ‘haircut’ of 30 per cent is perfectly plausible),
  • and, even with OBR, it is generally accepted (it is mentioned in the Bulletin) that the government would need to guarantee all the remaining deposits of the failed bank (otherwise depositors would rationally remove those funds ASAP from the failed bank)
  • and I’ve long  thought it likely that once the remaining funds of the failed bank are guaranteed, the government might also have to guarantee the deposits of the other banks in the system.  Banks rarely fail in isolation, and faced with the failure of a major banks, depositors might quite rationally prefer to shift their funds to the bank that now has the government guarantee.

And all this is before considering the huge pressure that would be likely to come on the New Zealand government, from the Australian government, to bail-out the combined ANZ group.  The damage to the overall ANZ brand, from allowing one very subsidiary to fail, would be quite large.  And Australian governments can play hardball.

So, the Minister of Finance (and PM) could apply OBR, but only by upsetting a huge number of voters (and voters’ families), upsetting the government of the foreign country most important to New Zealand, and still being left with large, fairly open-ended, guarantees on the books.

Or, they could simply write a cheque –  perhaps in some (superficially) harmonious trans-Tasman deal to jointly bail out parent and subsidiary  (the haggling would no doubt be quite acrimonious).  After all, our government accounts are in pretty reasonable shape by international standards.

And the real losses –  the bad loans –  have already happened.  It is just a question of who bears them.  And if one third of the population is bearing them –  in an institution that the Reserve Bank was supposed to have been supervising –  well, why not just spread them over all taxpayers?    And how reasonable is it to think that an 80 year pensioner, with $100000 in our largest bank, should have been expected to have been exercising more scrutiny and market discipline than our expert professional regulator (the Reserve Bank) succeeded in doing?  Or so will go the argument –  and it will get a lot of sympathy.

(There is provision in the OBR scheme for a “de minimis” amount below which the haircut might not apply.   If the de minimis amount is, say, $500 –  roughly a fortnightly New Zealand Superannuation amount for a couple –  it is neither here nor there for the scheme as a whole.  But a high de minimis amount looks a lot like ex post unfunded deposit insurance.)

Note that I’m not arguing that bailouts are “a good thing”, simply that having the OBR tool really does not dramatically alter the incentives politicians will face in dealing, at the time, with the imminent failure of a large bank.   And rational investor know that.  For the case of a large bank, OBR simply isn’t really a time-consistent strategy for politicians.

Some people at the Reserve Bank will accept the point, but argue that we still need OBR to have a credible weapon to wave in front of the Australians in a crisis.  If they think New Zealand might just be “crazy” enough to use it, it might  –  so it is argued – help us negotiate a slightly less unfavourable bail-out deal.  Perhaps.  But Australians can read domestic politics too.  I have no problem with having it in the toolkit –  perhaps it could be useful for a small bank  –  but no one should pretend that it solves bail-out risks and restores retail market discipline, red of tooth and claw.  And the probability of a bail-out, with a focus on protecting retail deposits, probably weakens market discipline at the margin even among wholesale investors.

And what are the precedents?  25 years ago the Bank of New Zealand was bailed out.  Yes, the government was the largest shareholder at the time, but I didn’t detect any sense –  at the very peak of the Douglas-Richardson era – that ownership determined whether the government of the day let the BNZ survive or fail.

More recently, the retail deposit guarantee scheme was put in place in late 2008 – not just for finance companies, but for the big banks too.  The decision was made by the previous Labour government – but it was endorsed by the Key/English led Opposition, and was recommended (in substance if not in precise detail) by the Reserve Bank and Treasury. I wrote many of the papers.

And more recently still, AMI was bailed out –  by the current government, on the recommendation of the Reserve Bank and Treasury.

In his speech, Fiennes note that

“it is of course true that many people expect governments to stand behind their deposits. That expectation was reinforced by the widespread Government guarantees (including in New Zealand) during the GFC.  The existence of an expectation, though, is not a sound reason to adopt deposit insurance”.

That might be true if depositors had no leverage.  But they do. It is called the ballot box, and politicians are very well aware of it.

If depositors, or policyholders, expect bailouts, and political leaders have incentives to respond to, and deliver on those expectations, then it may be a much less inferior option to adopt an explicit retail deposit insurance scheme upfront.

Deposit insurance need not be a substitute for OBR, but may actually make it a little more credible that OBR could be allowed to work.  If there is a bail-out, it will benefit not just New Zealand retail depositors, but wholesale lenders too, domestic and foreign.  There is likely to be much less political appetite for bailing out the wholesale creditors (especially the foreign ones), but a simple bailout does not enable one to distinguish.  By contrast, a properly specified deposit insurance scheme enables one to be very clear upfront which deposits are likely to be covered, and which not –  and to charge for that coverage accordingly.  In event of a bank failure, OBR could be applied to all creditors, with the deposit insurance scheme “reimbursing” the retail depositors to the extent defined in the scheme.  And in the event of a serious bank failure, the ability to impose loss on (particularly) foreign lenders (though in practice all wholesale creditors) is a net welfare gains to New Zealanders.  Letting losses fall on New Zealand retail depositors might be reasonable economics, but (a) it probably doesn’t work politically, and (b) it simply transfers the losses from one set of New Zealanders to another.

Deposit insurance schemes are not ideal –  and the Reserve Bank speech and article repeat some of the challenges.  But bailouts are not ideal either, and experience suggests very strongly that bailouts remain the preferred default option at the point of crisis.  As someone put it to me recently, in some sense if you don’t have an explicit limited deposit insurance scheme then, de facto, you have an implicit unlimited deposit insurance scheme (ie bailouts).  And reasonable depositors will know it.

And if deposit insurance schemes aren’t ideal, they are fairly ubiquitous.   As this recent IMF Working Paper points out (p32) every single advanced economy member of the IMF has an explicit deposit insurance scheme, with the exception of Israel, San Marino, and New Zealand.  San Marino aside, every European country, advanced or emerging, has such a scheme, and Africa is the only continent where a majority of countries do not have such schemes.  It has never been clear why the Reserve Bank thinks New Zealand can, or sensibly should, sustain being different, given the political economy pressures that all governments face.

And it is not as if deposit insurance has been withering since the financial crises of 2008/09.  As the IMF paper illustrates, coverage has often been extended, and co-payments wound back.

I noted this morning that, for all its insistence on having regular private data that creditors can’t get access to, the Reserve Bank continues to assert that, in effect, it has no financial “skin in the game” –  the risks are with creditors. In a second-best world, a deposit insurance scheme actually helps ensure that government agencies really do directly have skin in the game; financial risk if things go wrong.  That might actually sharpen accountability.

It was really rather naughty, and unhelpful, of the Reserve Bank not to have devoted some space to the political economy pressures, and the New Zealand bailouts/guarantees to which they (and The Treasury) have been party.  Of course, it might have been difficult to have done so, and would have undermined a good story, but it would have got us closer to better understanding the real choices and tradeoffs that societies face and make in this area, ex ante and ex post.

Of course, the decision on a deposit insurance scheme is not one for the Reserve Bank.  It is a government decision, and one that would require legislation to implement. It is understandable that the current government feels badly burned by the cost of the guarantee of South Canterbury Finance.  But given the incentives that governments will inevitably face if a major bank, or insurer, is on the brink of failure, it is surely time to shift direction, and put in place an explicit insurance scheme, for which depositors would be charged. Doing so would probably, overall, strengthen market disciplines a little, not weaken them as the Bank argues.  Bailouts of all creditors might still happen –  between Australian government pressure, and the threat of disrupted access to foreign funding markets –  but at least (a) the government would have raised some revenue in advance of the costs, and (b) we would be able to have more rational, and emotionally (and politically) plausible, arguments about the reasonableness of allowing unsophisticated investors who had taken little or no obvious risk (deposits in one of our larger banks) to face large unanticipated losses.

At interest.co.nz, Gareth Vaughan recently had a nice piece also making the case for deposit insurance in New Zealand.

 

Bank regulation: the Reserve Bank’s unease about transparency

The Reserve Bank has been firing out on-the-record speeches this week. I discussed the Governor’s troubling effort here, and may come back to that again in the next few days.  I probably won’t say much about the Assistant Governor’s lecture yesterday –  except perhaps to draw attention to his claim that ‘there are times when the Bank will know more about the economic situation and outlook than does the public or market participants’.  Really?   I guess the last three years, when the Governor has consistently failed to get inflation near the 2 per cent target, and has had to dramatically and grudgingly reverse his own rather strident policy stance, hasn’t been one of those times.

Perhaps more interesting were the two releases late yesterday afternoon on the role of market discipline in the context of prudential regulation of banks (in particular).   Toby Fiennes, the head of the Bank’s prudential supervision area delivered a speech to some of those he regulates headed “Regulation and the Importance of Market Discipline” , and an issue of the Bulletin by two of his staff headed “The importance of market discipline in the Reserve Bank’s prudential regime” was released.    In both of yesterday’s releases there is a refreshing reaffirmation of the importance of market discipline –  even if the actual direction of policy isn’t really that consistent with the rhetoric.

The Fiennes speech is a mix: in part a lecture on the Bank’s view of the importance of market discipline, and partly a report on the outcome of the Bank’s recent tidying up exercise, the so-called  “regulatory stocktake”.  I wrote about the results of that process here (and a mere four months after first requesting them I have recently had released to me around half of the submissions the Bank received on the stocktake consultation ) [1].

I wanted to touch on just two aspects of the stocktake material.  I was one of several submitters who had made the case that all submissions on Reserve Bank consultative documents should be published (as is now common practice in other government agencies and parliamentary select committees).  The Bank has always been very resistant to such openness. But in its release in December, there were encouraging signs

Our current approach is based on our understanding that respondents prefer to keep their submissions confidential. Prior feedback indicated that banks, in particular, were reticent to share cost information and the Reserve Bank is concerned that the publication of submissions would impact the quality and detail of the submission feedback. On the other hand we also recognise the importance of transparency in the policy-making process, so we will return to this issue and consult on a revised approach under which the default position would be that all submissions are published on our website (although submitters could ask to have any confidential information in submissions redacted).

Unfortunately, the discussion in last night’s speech –  when Fiennes went out among the banks –  was weaker than what they put out in December.

Some submitters suggested that we publish all written submissions on our public consultations. Our current approach is based on prior feedback, which indicated that respondents prefer to keep their submissions private on the grounds of commercial confidentiality. We will test this more rigorously with stakeholders. The alternative would be to publish all submissions by default unless submitters ask for them to be withheld or redacted.

Talk of a new default position of publication has disappeared.  What I wrote in December seems even more apposite in light of last night’s comments

I think this statement tells one a lot about the extent to which the Reserve Bank sees its clients as primarily the institutions it regulates, rather than the public the institution exists for.  I’m sure that banks would generally prefer to keep their submissions confidential, and it is precisely for that reason that their submissions, in particular, should be made public.  It is too easy for a cosy relationship to develop between the regulator and the regulated

I hope that the Reserve Bank remembers that its primary stakeholders are the public, and the representatives of the public (the Minister and members of Parliament), not the entities they are statutorily charged with regulating.

But to balance that unease, I want to give Fiennes kudos for one aspect of his speech. In my submission to the stocktake I had argued that if the Bank was serious about promoting market discipline, it shouldn’t be devoting undue time to refining disclosure statements, which the Bank quite openly states don’t contain the information the Bank itself uses. Instead, I argued, the Bank should require that all the private information the Reserve Bank now collects should be published on the relevant bank’s website at the same time it is supplied to the Bank.  Recall that the Bank is keen to emphasise that creditors, not the Reserve Bank or the Crown, bear the losses in the event of a bank failure.

The Bank’s published response to the submissions did not deal with that proposal at all.  But last night’s speech did.  Here is what Fiennes said

As some of you may have read, several submitters argued that we should publish all of the information we receive through private reporting, potentially publishing a monthly dashboard of this information.

While this principle has some appeal, there are two main reasons why we do not consider it appropriate.

First, the potential trade-off between timeliness and data quality. We sometimes accept a marginal reduction in data quality in private reporting in exchange for receiving the information quickly. While this is appropriate for supervisory purposes, public disclosure needs to maintain a high minimum accuracy in order to support the credibility of the regime. This is underscored by the penalties in the legislation for false disclosure, and is an issue we are giving careful thought to in the design of the dashboard.

Second, there is the issue of commercial sensitivity. Often the private data we received is commercially sensitive, or might be open to misinterpretation if released without the appropriate context – especially if this was occurring in a situation of rapidly rising financial system risk.

At least now we can better understand the Bank’s objections. But I don’t find the counter-arguments persuasive.

Fiennes asserts that the Bank can “sometimes” live with a “marginal reduction in data quality…in exchange for receiving the information quickly”,  but that they can’t possibly expose the public to this “marginal reduction”.  But it is the money owned by the public that is at stake in these banks: Reserve Bank staff and management have nothing directly at stake.  More generally, the Bank doesn’t seem to recognise that all sorts of real and financial markets trade on imperfect information all the time –  in monetary policy, the constant revisions to GDP data for years afterwards are just the most obvious example.  If the information is sufficiently valuable to the Reserve Bank that it will use statutory powers to compel banks to supply it (without charge) that information, then such timely information should be at least as valuable to the public who are investing with the banks.  If the data really helps shed light on the financial positions of banks, investors have more use for it than officials.

The Reserve Bank’s other counter-argument is “commercial sensitivity”.  But if the Reserve Bank really needs this timely information to do its job, how can depositors and other lenders not need it to evaluate the changing nature of the risks they are running?  No doubt the same sorts of arguments were run when disclosure statements were first developed in the 1990s.  Fiennes is also concerned that data might be “open to misinterpretation if released without the appropriate context” –  but nothing stops the disclosing bank itself, or the Reserve Bank , or any private sector commentators providing that context.  Any data can be misinterpreted   – and can also be explained.  Fiennes amplifies the point by arguing that misinterpretation is perhaps especially likely “in a situation of rapidly rising financial system risk”.   But disclosure isn’t overly valuable to any creditor in good times – the value of having that information is precisely when actual and perceived risks are rising.  And, to be boringly repetitive, it is depositors’ and investors’ money that is at stake.

Here was some of my discussion of the issues in my original submission:

Moving in the direction discussed just above would, of course, represent a substantial change in  approach.  Timely statistical returns of the sort banks supply to the Reserve Bank can’t first go through a full audit sign-off and director attestation, but the Reserve Bank itself –  by its own  revealed preferences –  clearly thinks that in terms of knowing what is going on on a timely basis, those protections are less important than getting timely information.  If things are very timely there will almost inevitably be the occasional error, but that is not an argument against the idea.  After all, even Statistics New Zealand (perhaps even the Reserve Bank) occasionally finds mistakes in its data.  The concern shouldn’t be errors –  people are human and will err –  but about the risk of being deceived.  But adequate protections against deliberate attempts to deceive either the Reserve Bank or creditors (by deliberately supplying erroneous or misleading information) surely either already exist in statute or common law, or could be legislated separately.  And the fact that the Reserve Bank’s own analysts would be reliant on the same data that were going public would provide an additional layer of comfort –  since the Bank is readily able to ask, and require answers to, probing follow-up questions.

I am also not suggesting an absolutist approach to this issue.  I have no problem with the answers to  ad hoc inquiries by the Reserve Bank of an individual bank not being published.  And in times when an individual institution may be approaching crisis, there probably inevitably needs to be a degree of confidentiality around the handling of that detailed information involved in crisis management (although such material should probably still be discoverable after the event).  Indeed, protecting that sort of information was a part of the justification for the (now abused) section 105 secrecy provisions in the Reserve Bank Act.  There is no foolproof dividing line, but I would suggest as a starting point that any statistical returns which are (a) regular, and (b) required of all (or a significant subset of) banks should be subject to my immediate disclosure rule.  And perhaps the Reserve Bank Board could offer an attestation in its Annual Report that it has satisfied itself that staff and management are operating the system in a way that ensures all regular supervisory information is being made available to depositors and other creditors.

I still think the case for full and immediate publication of all regular bank statistical returns is strong.

New Zealand’s regime around depositor protection is extremely unusual internationally –  something I will come back to in a follow-up post.   We don’t protect depositors.  Perhaps keeping information private –  having the real oil only going to the Reserve Bank –  might be acceptable in some idealised world in which bank regulators were consistently wise, insightful, benevolent and consistently right. (“we’ll look after everything for you”).   But they aren’t.  They are human beings, and their track record (around the world) isn’t particularly good.  That isn’t a comment about the Reserve Bank of New Zealand in particular –  it hasn’t been put to the test in the last 20 years –  but about bank regulators more generally (and other regulators for that matter).

Regulators simply do not have the incentives to process and interpret information correctly –  and it isn’t their money at stake.  Sometimes they get too cosy with those they regulate.  At other times, they get too cosy with their political masters. And often enough – being human –  they simply pursue their own bureaucratic interests –  a bigger agency, with more power, more information, not too much scrutiny and a quiet life.  There isn’t much reason to think that Reserve Bank regulators will consistently make better use of ‘private data’ from banks better than the people who have lent to those banks will.  Disclosure can be messy, and bureaucrats abhor messiness.  But the contest of ideas and interpretations, and the intense scrutiny of available information (partial as it might often be), is the essence of competitive market processes.  Tidiness, not so much.   If regulators need data promptly, so do those who invest with the banks they regulate.

 

[1] The Bank told me a week ago they were going to post that release on their website (here), but have not yet done so.  If anyone wants a copy of those submissions please email me.  [UPDATE: The Bank has now posted the release.]