Tweaky tools

For the first 20 years or so of inflation targeting in New Zealand, there was a near-constant hankering for other instruments to “help out” monetary policy. In the early days of getting inflation under control, it was little more than ritual incantations (the team I ran included them every month in our papers to the Minister) that it would help, adjustment would be easier, if only there was labour market deregulation, reduced trade protection, and tougher fiscal policy. In the Brash years, his colleagues became very familiar with the Governor’s hankering for what we (or he) called “tweaky tools”, things that at the margin might make a difference, particularly perhaps in easing the exchange rate pressures that used to be such a feature of New Zealand monetary policy tightening cycles. There was even the pesky visiting US academic in the mid-90s who used his public lecture to suggest that discretionary fiscal policy should be handed over to the Reserve Bank (we winced). It wasn’t so different in the pre-2008/09 Bollard years. At the then Minister’s urging we and Treasury ran an entire Supplementary Stabilisation Instruments projects in 2005/06, culminating a year later in a scheme for a discretionary Mortgage Interest Levy, a scheme the then Minister was tantalised by, sufficient to consult the Opposition, but eventually shut down work on only when National walked away. At about the same time, yet another invited visiting academic was openly proposing a variable GST as a supplementary stabilisation instrument. In the same vein a few years later, Labour in 2014 campaigned on giving the Reserve Bank power to vary Kiwisaver contribution rates, to assist monetary policy in the cyclical (inflation) stabilisation role Parliament has assigned it.

Of course, between mid 2007 and mid 2021, there were hardly any OCR increases, and those there were were quite small and short-lived (unnecessary in the first place as it happens). And since around 2010 New Zealand real exchange rate fluctuations have been much more muted than we had become accustomed to (over the decades from 1985, they were not only highly salient in political debate but also inside the Reserve Bank).

And if big cyclical swings in the real exchange rate still haven’t resumed, big OCR increases have.

And with it talk of spreading burdens, easing loads, and finding supplementary tools seems to be back. There was an article in the Herald a couple of weeks ago sympathising with indebted households who, it was claimed, are bearing the brunt of the belated anti-inflation fight.

(I wouldn’t usually be very sympathetic with people who took big mortgages when house prices were rocketing on the back of pandemic-policy low interest rates and didn’t lock in, say, five or seven year fixed rates, except that……..the Reserve Bank itself by buying up $50+ bn on longish-term government debt at the same time did rather tend to suggest to the borrowing public that rates weren’t likely to go up much – after all, which responsible government agency would expose its stakeholders (taxpayers) to a meaningful risk of $10+bn of financial losses.)

And that prompted Don Brash to enter the conversation, reviving a call he had first made in 2008 and suggesting that the Reserve Bank be given the power to vary the petrol excise tax as an additional counter-cyclical tool to assist monetary policy and spread the burden. This is reported and discussed in this Herald piece today, which in turn draws from one of Don’s own blog posts. Don ends his post with this claim

But it would have the huge advantage of spreading the social effects of controlling the inflation rate.

I disagree, quite strongly, with Don’s proposal, for a variety of practical and principled reasons, and would do even on a best-case model (say, legislation limited the extent of the Bank’s discretion and revenues were properly and formally ring-fenced).

(In the Herald article, ANZ chief economist Sharon Zollner is also quite sceptical, adding this tantalisingly radical observation – topic for another post another day:

She said the more salient questions we should be asking were not what tools should we use to try to steer the economy, but rather, should we try to do it at all, given the limitations of economic forecasting? Might the costs outweigh the benefits?

Don is quite right that (as we saw last year), petrol excise taxes can be adjusted very quickly and the effects are also typically seen in retail prices very quickly. He suggests that as the price elasticity of demand for petrol is quite limited, any increase in petrol taxes will quite quickly dampen households’ other spending, in turn dampening inflation pressures. There are certainly plenty of households who are quite cash-flow constrained, but whether the effect exists to a material extent in aggregate would need rather more careful and formal review (reflecting on my own behaviour, I’m also a bit sceptical).

But even if we grant that the effect is real and, whatever the effect actually is, perhaps fast-working, there are lots of other problems. These include:

  • the temporary petrol excise tax cut of 2022/23 was 25 cents a litre.  As far I can see, the direct fiscal costs of that were about $1 billion over 15 months.  Even if it was $1 billion for a year, that is about 0.25 per cent of GDP.   And although many economists, including me, pointed out that the income effect of this cut (and the associated road user charge and public transport subsidies) was inflationary, I’ve not seen anyone suggest it was a decisive factor in explaining core inflation outcomes over the last year or so.  Quadruple the effect and one might be talking more serious macroeconomic impacts, but that would require giving the Reserve Bank discretion to make much larger changes in excise taxes than any Minister or Parliament has ever made before.   Sold as an explicitly temporary effect, a cyclical stabilisation adjustment of this sort would probably result in less demand effects than, say, an excise tax increase known to be permanent.
  • Don Brash argues that petrol excise taxes are easy to change. Much less so (as we saw last year in the rushed package) are road user changes for diesel-fuelled vehicles).  The Brash scheme doesn’t seem to envisage adjusting road user charges, but to do one and not the other –  as part of a new permanent stabilisation model –  would seem simply politically untenable.  He also recognises that electric vehicles are becoming more of an issue than they were when he first dreamed up the scheme, but says “Admittedly, with the growing use of electric vehicles there may come a time when varying the excise tax on petrol would have little effect on aggregate demand. But that time is still some way away.”  It seems likely that EVs will soon, as they should, face road user charges, but again the politically tone-deaf nature of the suggestion that the unelected central bank should be able to whack on huge tax imposts on one lot of drivers but not others (the “others” often stylised as being upper income anyway) is staggering.  And if you are tantalised by a thought “oh, but we can encourage people towards EVs”, remember that any such scheme would almost certainly have to be symmetrical…….
  • As Brash acknowledges, one downside of his scheme is that increasing fuel excise taxes to fight inflation will itself, at least initially, boost CPI inflation.   From a central bank accountability perspective this itself isn’t fatal (the target could be re-expressed as one for CPI inflation ex indirect taxes, and the fuel excise effect won’t show up directly in the better analytical core inflation measures), but…….one of the things we know about survey measures of inflation expectations is that they seem to be quite heavily influenced by headline CPI developments (and you can be sure media will keep highlighting headline effects).  We don’t have a very good sense of how those expectations are then reflected in behaviour (spending, borrowing, price and wage setting) but it is unlikely to be helpful –  and especially if we were talking of $1 a litre excise tax changes)
  • It is certainly true that there are plenty of cash-flow constrained households.  For better or worse, however, many of the most cash-flow constrained households also benefit from formal inflation adjustments (welfare benefit indexation), which directly undercut the cash-flow argument Brash is relying on.   The tendency of governments to at least inflation-index the minimum wage works in the same direction (and if neither adjustment is immediate, the central bank should be focused on medium-term inflation prospects, not one quarter possible effects).
  • People are rational.  The MPC meets seven times a year.   Given the prospect that seven times a year, on pre-announced dates, the fuel excise would be up for grabs, behaviour will change, with people either queuing for petrol the morning of the MPC meeting, or holding off as much as possible until just after.     Especially if the prospective excise adjustments are large enough to be economically meaningful (and the road user side is even more challenging if it were to be included).
  • It is a long-established principle of our system of government, dating back centuries, that taxes should only be imposed and adjusted by elected Parliaments (or at very least by formulae fixed by Parliament, as with indexation).   Back when the Mortgage Interest Levy (see above) was being devised (I was the key RB deviser), I recall telling Alan Bollard that I would join the marches in the streets against any notion of taxation without representation.   Same should go for petrol excise tax levies.  It is all rather redolent of Muldoon’s proposal from the 1970s (which was firmly rejected) for the minister to be able to do modest adjustments to tax rates for cyclical stabilisation purposes.  It is the sort of argument that has technocratic appeal, but no democratic appeal.  And before anyone suggests parallels, the rate at which a central bank pays interest to a bank that chooses to deposit with it is not a tax.
  • The Brash proposal seems to have no framework within which the MPC should decide whether to use a fuel excise tool, and to what extent it should use one tool rather than another.  Perhaps overall accountability for inflation – weak as that now seems to be –  would be unchanged, but we’d be opening the door to the whims of 7 unelected people, several with very little technical expertise either, to decide whether to whack up the fuel excise tax or whack up the OCR.   There are huge distributional implications from such choices, and no framework. opening the way (among other things) to extensive lobbying from vested interests preferring one rather than the other.   That seems, to put it politely, unappealing.
  • One of the elements of the Mortgage Interest Levy proposal that exercised our minds a lot was how to ring-fence the revenue.   There wasn’t much point in an additional tax, which might dampen some forms of demand, if the prospect of that money meant governments felt free to spend more.   One can devise all sorts of clever-clogs institutional arrangements, but in the end public revenue is public revenue, net public debt is net public debt, and cost of living pressures and elections are very real.   This might not be an insuperable obstacle, but money pots will tempt politicians (government and Opposition).
  • Brash justifies his proposal on the grounds of mitigating the “social effects” of controlling inflation.  That may well be a laudable goal, but it is one for governments.  This year, however, the government has chosen to run a much bigger fiscal stimulus than it had planned even at the end of last year, on a scale swamping the plausible extent of any fuel excise tax tool, at a time when inflation is still a severe issue.    Had they been at all concerned, there were options, within current legislative and governance frameworks.  The government chose not to take them (and to a detached observer there is little concrete sign National would really have done much different).

Some of the points above matter more than others, and some will matter more to some than to others. But overall, it seems an unappealing proposal. Actually, I’d be rather surprised if the Reserve Bank itself were at all keen, at least after half an hour’s thought.

In the original Herald article a couple of weeks ago, the author ended this way

Quite.

Inflation outlooks

I was filling in the latest Reserve Bank Survey of Expectations form the other day. If one ever needed to be reminded that macroeconomic forecasting is a mug’s game, or wanted a lesson in humility, all one needs do is keep a file of one’s successive entries to that survey. Coming on the back of the latest annual inflation rate of 6 per cent, it was sobering to look back at the two-year ahead expectations I’d written down in 2021 (as I happened, I missed the July 2021 survey so can’t give you my exact number, but suffice to say it would have borne no relation to 6 per cent).

I wasn’t alone. This is what two-year ahead expectations were each quarter from March 2019 (done around the end of January) to September 2021 (done around the end of July). With something of a scare in the June quarter of 2020, the average respondent generally saw medium-term inflation sticking pretty comfortably in the target range the government had set for the Reserve Bank MPC.

As the Reserve Bank often likes to point out, these expectations measures haven’t historically had a great record as forecasts. In fact, here are the outcomes for the dates at which these two year ahead expectations were sought (so the Sept 2021 quarter survey asked about inflation for the year to June 2023). I’ve shown both the headline CPI and the Bank’s sectoral factor model measure of core inflation. Although the question asks about CPI inflation, in some ways core outcomes are a better comparator since no one is going to forecast out-of-the-blue changes in government charges or taxes, or oil prices, two years hence.

The average private commentator/forecaster who completed the surveys has been pretty hopeless.

Unfortunately for us, since it is the Reserve Bank MPC that not only makes monetary policy but is, notionally at least, accountable for stewardship and outcomes, the Reserve Bank was a little worse still

The Reserve Bank’s projections were consistently lower than those of the average surveyed respondents over the period relevant to the inflation outcomes of the last couple of years, and by margins that (by the standards of surveys like this) are really quite large. But the underlying story is even worse, because the Reserve Bank runs the Survey of Expectations so as to have the data available when making their own projections. Thus, the Survey of Expectations is open to respondents from late last week until Wednesday, but the August MPS is not until 17 August, with forecasts finalised perhaps on the 12th. The Reserve Bank has consistently more information than the survey respondents, including both the survey responses themselves and the full quarterly suite of labour market data (and other bits and pieces of extra data from here and abroad). All else equal, the Reserve Bank projections should be at least a bit closer to outcomes than the average respondents’ expectations, even if both lots of people were making the same misjudgements about the underlying story. Time has value.

The picture would be more stark again if I could effectively illustrate respective OCR expectations over the period. Both the Bank and survey respondents are, in principle, providing endogenous policy forecasts (ie both allow the OCR, and any other policy levers at the MPC’s disposal, to change), but the survey respondents are only asked about the OCR out to a year ahead (and, more recently, 10 years ahead, but that is less relevant here). And during the worst of the Covid period, the Bank wasn’t publishing OCR projections, but rather an “unconstrained OCR” path, which went quite deeply negative, even though the actual OCR couldn’t go that low. But it looks as though not only were the Bank’s inflation outlooks more wrong than the private survey respondents (answering several weeks earlier), but they were probably based on looser monetary conditions than private respondents were assuming.

We don’t know where annual inflation is going from here, or when and how quickly it will get back to around the 2 per cent the MPC is supposed to have been focused on. But if we add a couple more surveys and sets of MPS projections to the chart (bringing us up to numbers done in early 2022) it seems pretty likely that the Reserve Bank MPC projections will still have been more wrong than the private survey respondents were (after all two of the four quarterly numbers that will make up December 2023’s annual inflation have already been published). All this in the period of the biggest inflation outbreak, and monetary policy error, in decades.

I was on record last year as opposing the reappointment of the Governor (and, for what it is worth, the external MPC members). In a post back in November I included a list of 20+ reasons why Orr should not have been reappointed. None of them were the actual inflation outcomes.

I’ve tended to emphasise that both central banks (here and abroad), and markets and private forecasters, to a greater or lesser extent really badly misjudged inflation. And that is true. But central banks, and specifically their monetary policy committees, were charged with the job of keeping inflation near target, and given a lot of resource to do the supporting analysis and research. If they had done only as badly as the average private sector person over that critical period, perhaps there might be reason to make allowance (but these people voluntarily put themselves forward as best placed to do the price stability job, and are amply rewarded for it (financially and in terms of prestige). And in New Zealand at least, they did worse.

What is more, and this gets me closer to my list of reasons why none of the decisionmakers should have been reappointed, not once have we had from them (individually or collectively) an apology – for the massive economic dislocations and redistributions their mistakes led to (unwittingly no doubt, but they purport to be experts) – or even a serious attempt at robust self-examination and review, with signs that they now understand why they got things so wrong. Not a serious speech, not a serious research paper (or whole series), really not much at all (yes, there was their five-year self review late last year, but as I noted at the time there really wasn’t much openness there either). Not even an acknowledgement that they – the experts who took on the job – did worse than the respondents to their own surveys through an utterly critical period.

Inflation, monetary policy, and central bank spin

The CPI data out yesterday were not good news.

Annual headline inflation was, more or less as expected, down, but at around 6 per cent is miles from the 2 per cent target midpoint the Reserve Bank’s MPC has been required to focus on delivering. Much more importantly, core inflation measures show little or no sign of any reduction.

Six months ago I had been intrigued by this chart

It looked as though a reasonable case could then be made that core inflation had peaked a year earlier and was now falling (albeit still far too high).

But jump forward to today and the chart now looks like this

If it still suggests a peak at the start of last year (at least on one of the measures), it is no longer a picture of (core) inflation falling now. (NB: You cannot put much weight on the absolute level of the numbers shown here because for some, unknown, reason SNZ persists in doing the calculations on not seasonally adjusted data, which can materially affect the level of quarterly estimates.)

If you look at a range of exclusion measures (CPI ex this, that or the other), the quarterly picture for Q2 looks a little more promising (but analytical measures such as those above are increasingly used for a reason).

On an annual basis, a whole bunch of measures centre on core inflation of perhaps just over 6 per cent.

Focusing on just two big individual price movements, the CPI ex petrol is up 7.1 per cent for the year, and the CPI ex international airfares is up 5.7 per cent.

The contrast between New Zealand

and Canada (where the central bank has the same target as ours) is striking

Rightly or wrongly, the Canadian central bank last week still judged it appropriate and necessary to raise its policy interest rate.

Over the period since the OCR was introduced, the New Zealand policy rate has typically been a lot higher than Canada’s (for the same inflation target since 2002): the median difference has been 1.5 percentage points. At present, the difference is unusually small even though our inflation numbers look quite a bit worse than Canada’s

If you think Canada is an obscure comparator, the story is, if anything, a bit more stark relative to the US where core inflation measures have also been falling.

And yet having chosen – and it is pure discretionary choice by the MPC – to review the OCR last week, just a few days BEFORE the infrequent New Zealand inflation data was released, the MPC then declared itself “confident” things were on track to get inflation back to target with policy rates at current levels.

Given how wrong they (and most other central banks) have been over the last three years, it is difficult to know how any bunch of monetary policymakers, with any self-knowledge and introspection at all, can declare themselves “confident” of anything about inflation outlooks. But what could possibly have led our lot to such a conclusion a week BEFORE the (quarterly only) inflation data? Once again, it isn’t looking great for them……and I guess it will be fingers crossed at the RB that the quarterly labour market data out early next month are much weaker. But the best official monthly data we have don’t seem that promising.

(As a reminder, it is not too late to apply to become a member of the Monetary Policy Committee although it is unclear that genuinely able people would be that keen to join a body led by underqualified uninterested people and where any genuine insight or challenge is unlikely, on the evidence to date, to be welcomed.)

I’ve always been reluctant to suggest that the MPC, or even Orr, were partisan. Mostly, they just seem not very good, something shown up more starkly in challenging times, and prone to questionable self-serving spin (even in front of Parliament). But since the May MPS I have started to wonder, and the nagging doubt was reinforced last week.

The Minister of Finance brought down the government’s annual Budget on Thursday 18 May. The Reserve Bank’s Monetary Policy Statement was a few days later, on Wednesday 24 May. I was travelling so most of my scattered comments were on Twitter.

On a current affairs show on 20 May, the Minister of Finance claimed that the Budget would not add to pressures on inflation or monetary policy.

This was utterly at odds with the material published by The Treasury. Treasury estimates and publishes a series for the “fiscal impulse”. This measure was designed specifically for the Reserve Bank to give a sense of how, particularly over the forecast period, fiscal policy choices were going to be affecting demand and inflation pressures.

All else equal a falling deficit or rising surplus act as a bit of a drag on inflation, and vice versa for rising deficits or falling surpluses.

This chart was from the Treasury HYEFU published last December and incorporating the government’s then fiscal plans, as formally advised to the Treasury. As you can see, for each of the forecast years, the estimated impulse was negative (the overall accounts were still expected to be in deficit for most of the period, but the projected deficit was shrinking). At the time, most monetary policy interest would have been on the (highlighted) 23/24 year – showing a moderate negative impulse – since it was the period that monetary policy choices would most affect (and anything beyond 23/24 was little more than vapourware anyway, with an election in the middle).

This is how the same chart looked in the May Budget documents (Treasury’s BEFU)

For the key year – the one for which this Budget directly related – the estimated fiscal impulse had shifted from something moderately negative to something reasonably materially positive. The difference is exactly 2.5 percentage points of GDP. That is a big shift in an important influence on the inflation outlook – which in turn should influence the monetary policy outlook – concentrated right in the policy window.

My point is not to debate the merits of the Budget (political parties will differ on that) but to highlight the macro implications of aggregate fiscal choices as estimated by The Treasury, and how utterly at odds with the Treasury’s analysis the Minister’s spin was.

Ministers – and perhaps campaigning ones – will say whatever suits them, whatever relationship (or otherwise) what suits bears to hard analysis and advice.

But one of the key reasons why societies have chosen to delegate the operation of monetary policy to autonomous central bankers is that the central bankers are thought more likely to operate without fear or favour, calling the data and events as they calmly and professionally see it. So, you’d have thought, with a Monetary Policy Statement a few days after the Budget one might have expected some serious detached analysis of the updated Budget fiscal numbers, as they affected demand and inflation. Either citing the Treasury’s estimates or perhaps presenting analysis explaining why the Bank thought the fiscal influence might be different than the Treasury did (the latter using a framework designed specifically for monetary policy purposes). After all, in their previous MPS, MPC minutes had explicitly noted that “members viewed the risks to inflation pressure from fiscal policy as skewed to the upside”.

Central bankers, including particularly at our Reserve Bank, have long avoided taking a stance on government spending and revenue choices. Mostly, they also avoid taking a stance of deficits and surpluses. Those are political choices, and particularly in modestly-indebted countries (like New Zealand) it doesn’t greatly matter to monetary policy whether the budget is in deficit or surplus. It matters way less whether one has a high spending and high taxing government or a low spending or low taxing government, and so it is rare – and appropriately so – for the Reserve Bank to be commenting on either spending or revenue choices. What matters (about fiscal policy) in updating the inflation outlook is changes in the discretionary component of the fiscal deficit/surplus (basically, what the fiscal impulse is trying to capture). This snippet (from a Bollard-years MPS) captures the general approach.

But how did the MPC treat things in the May 2023 MPS, coming just a few days after that very big increase in the expected fiscal impulse for the immediately approaching year, at a time when inflation (core and headline) was way outside the target range and the OCR had had to be raised aggressively?

The only uses of the terms “fiscal” or “fiscal policy” (“fiscal impulse” doesn’t appear at all) are in this paragraph from the minutes. Even here – even that final sentence – it is consistent minimisation.

But these are the only references. In the one page policy statement, there is no link drawn from fiscal choices to the inflation outlook, and only this rather odd (for a central bank) detached observation: “Broader government spending is anticipated to decline in inflation-adjusted terms and in proportion to GDP.” So what, one was left wondering…..unless the Governor and his colleagues had taken to playing politics, perhaps to help out a Minister and his colleagues who seem more disposed to the Governor’s way of doing/saying things than, say, the Opposition parties (who openly opposed his reappointment) might be.

Perhaps it wouldn’t even be worth highlighting if this were the only such reference. But it isn’t, by any means. Recall, there are no references in the body of the document to fiscal policy, fiscal impulses, fiscal deficits, OBEGAL, or changes in any of these. But there is a whole section devoted specifically to government spending, on top of the couple of references I’ve already quoted. And the focus there is not on the horizon relevant to May’s monetary policy choices, or the inflation outlook over the next 12-18 months but over the “medium term”, when who knows which government will be in charge and what their spending preferences and priorities will be.

It is quite right that their projections – which simply use Treasury numbers as a base – have real government consumption and investment spending (the bits they publish numbers for) flat for the next several years.

That might raise some interesting issues, including for supporters of the current government who favour lots of government spending (is it really consistent with your values that per capita spending is going to fall quite sharply?, would it prove politically sustainable? and so on).

But it is of almost no relevance to monetary policy. And omits really major bits of the fiscal story (on the spending side, all of transfers and finance costs, and all of the revenue side). Central banks should be mostly interested in shocks to the deficit/surplus outlook. But not, this year, it appears the RBNZ.

The Bank and the MPC seemed to minimise any story about the fiscal contribution to the outlook for inflation and monetary policy (you know, things like inflation still being outside the target range, even with a high OCR, for protracted periods. Those fiscal impulse charts/numbers don’t get a mention. But neither do simple stats like the fact that in December’s HYEFU, on then government plans, Treasury thought the OBEGAL deficit for 2023/24 would be 0.1% of GDP. By May’s Budget, government plans meant a forecast deficit that year of 1.8% of GDP. These are really big changes, playing down to near-invisibility by our supposedly non-partisan independent MPC.

It was all brought back to the front of mind last week when, out of the blue, this observation appeared in the OCR statement

Broader government spending is anticipated to decline in inflation-adjusted terms and in proportion to GDP. 

If you relied on Reserve Bank commentary, you’d just never know that, in the period current monetary policy choices are directly affecting, discretionary fiscal policy choices (overall balance and all that) had added, quite considerably, to inflation pressures in this year’s Budget. It doesn’t take much to guess which line the Minister of Finance will have preferred – and it isn’t the one that actually aligns with the Bank’s own responsibilities.

I am really reluctant to believe that partisan positioning is at work, even if (if it is happening) “just” for institutional self-protection reasons. But I find it difficult to see a compelling alternative explanation for the MPC’s approach to fiscal analysis and fiscal impulses in the last couple of months.

Perhaps the Opposition parties will view the Reserve Bank more charitably. But on what has been put before us, there is no reason for them to do so.

Project Cricket (and other nonsense)

I’ve been reading the papers released the other day by Treasury (in one case written jointly with IRD) on the Minister of Finance’s hankering to tax Australian banks more heavily, retrospectively.

There seem to be three such papers, a 10 February Treasury Report, a short 17 February Treasury aide-memoire, and a 10 March joint Treasury/IRD report. Nothing appears to have been withheld from the first two, but there are several, quite lengthy, bits withheld from the 10 March paper, in many cases apparently references to legal advice officials may have received.

The 10 February paper is titled “Windfall gains in the New Zealand banking sector, and responses”, apparently part of something called “Project Cricket”. Retrospective taxes targeted at companies the Minister of Finance doesn’t like and are just considered politically ripe for the plucking are…..really not cricket. But perhaps that irony escaped both the authors and the Minister. The paper is signed by Treasury’s Manager, Tax Strategy, and as tends to be the way with Treasury, when one looks him up he seemed to have no background at all in tax (or banking), and little in New Zealand either. It wasn’t a promising start.

It is a fairly long paper (24 pages)

The Minister already had his enemies in sight but wanted a fishing expedition as well.

The Treasury paper wasn’t a very compelling piece of work. Without any serious analytical framework at all, it (slightly grudgingly, or perhaps just diplomatically) concludes “there is no clear evidence that banks made windfall profits during the recovery from COVID-19”. And instead of concluding strongly that since there is not the slightest evidence of anything that could seriously be called “windfall profits” and thus there was no serious analytical case at all for anything like a “windfall profits tax”, we just get this lame conclusion

as if otherwise it would okay.

As for those other sectors

All based on this

Quite how the agricultural sector “may have derived windfall gains” is left to the reader (and us) to guess. It all seems very loose and incoherent stuff. (Had one been interested in regulatorily-induced windfall profits, surely one place to look might have been the supermarkets that were given a monopoly position during Covid lockdowns at the expense of other food retailers, but….lets not encourage them.)

So lacking in any serious analytical framework is the discussion around “windfall profits” that Treasury apparently never thinks to point out that an unexpected burst of inflation (perhaps a 10 per cent change in the price level, engineered – albeit inadvertently – by the government’s own central bank), came closest to a true set of windfall gains and losses. Who gained – entirely unexpectedly? Why, that would be people with long-term fixed rate debt. And which party has the most long-term fixed rate debt on issue? Why, that would be the government itself. On the other hand, holders of fixed rate financial instruments were subject to fairly marked, close to genuinely “windfall”, losses.

I mentioned there windfall losses. That is more than the Treasury (or Treasury/IRD) advice ever does. Over time, true windfalls, such as they are, are pretty randomly distributed – gains, losses, sectors, individuals. But of course there was no sense here of a coherent or comprehensive approach to the issue, some systematic search for windfalls across the economy that the government might tax (or compensate). No, the MInister had his four Australian banks in target. With not the slightest evidence – even with Treasury doing what it could to try to find it for him – that there was anything that anyone other than the Green Party could seriously consider “windfall profits”.

And in this first paper, officials didn’t even think to point out that retrospective legislation of any sort – but perhaps particular one targeted at four of the king’s (or his Minister of Finance’s) enemies is generally pretty abhorrent. If anything, they seemed to quite like the idea of a retrospective tax (check the table on p15 of the release). On whatever strange definition of “coherence” these officials were using a retrospective tax aimed by four companies, when the advice said there was no serious evidence of windfall profits, also apparently raised no concerns.

(In passing, I would note that the Treasury is quite open in calling the Reserve Bank’s Funding for Lending programme a direct “subsidy” to banks. That is, perhaps unsurprisingly, not language the Reserve Bank has used. But as Treasury notes, there does seem to have been reasonable evidence that the subsidy – put in place as a conscious matter of policy – had mostly been passed on the customers.)

Somewhat surprisingly, when providing the Minister with advice on a tax that would be targeted at four specific Australian-owned companies, there is no discussion at all of the likely reaction of the companies’ owner, or of their government, or of whether and how such an arbitrary tax might raise difficulties in the trans-Tasman halls of financial regulators. Oddly, in all three papers there was not a single mention of the fact that the parents of these four wholly-owned companies also had active operating branches in New Zealand, and what (if any) implications there might be for the future mix between branch and subsidiary business.

Despite Treasury’s recommendation in that 10 February paper, the Minister of Finance must have disagreed. The 17 February aide memoire ( 2 pages only) sets out briefly options that could be done for the Budget, then only three months away. They were retrospective and prospective levies. This was what they had to say about the former

There seems to be no sense that this would be something of a constitutional outrage. Sure, they say they were checking whether there were legal risks (perhaps anything in CER?), but as they and the Minister know Parliament in New Zealand is sovereign and the government easily has 61 votes for budget legislation.

This paper was for a meeting with the Minister on 20 February. The Minister was apparently undeterred.

The final paper in this suite is joint Treasury/IRD report of 10 March (also referring to “Project Cricket”). The introduction to that paper’s Executive Summary illustrates just how far off the rails the Minister was heading.

It was bad enough that the Minister was seriously considering a retrospective tax restricted to four foreign companies he didn’t like, in the face of official advice that there was no evidence of anything seriously akin to “windfall profits”, but now he was proposing such an arbitrary tax-grab specifically to help cover a cost pressure elsewhere in his budget which had nothing whatever to do with the four companies he wanted to tax or any of their activities. One hopes that privately officials were well and truly rolling their eyes by this point.

One might acknowledge that this advice – or perhaps another captain’s call from Hipkins – finally brought this work stream to a halt, but it simply wasn’t very good advice (at least based on what the government has chosen to release). Mightn’t one, for example, have expected some serious reference to a likely Australian reaction? Mightn’t one have expected some serious discussion of the precedent such an arbitrary tax might establish (actual or perceptions)? There is some reference to it – amid a weird sentence that talks about “the favourable position of New Zealand as an investment destination” – on what metric one might ask? – but it is all very muted. There is no discussion at all of the intellectual incoherence of picking on individual profitable firms ministers don’t like and not (say) responding symmetrically when unexpected sharp falls in profits happen (perhaps officials thought it not worth dignifying this nonsense on stilts?). There is no mention of the branches, or anything serious on the possible reduction in the availability of debt finance to New Zealand households and small and medium businesses (really big businesses can finance globally). We even find abstract comments, no doubt tantalising to the Minister, that “in theory, a one-off retrospective tax will not affect behaviour”. That sort of line might be fine from a traineee analyst fresh out of a basic university course, but this was serious budget advice from responsible Treasury and IRD officials

In what they published (perhaps it was in what was withheld, though there is no obvious reason to withhold_, there is also no reference at all to the New Zealand legislation guidelines, which state

Pretty sure the Minister not liking four particular foreign companies isn’t one of those “limited circumstances” in the final bullet.

What was proposed was an abomination, but – even though they didn’t favour what the Minister was hankering for – you get little sense of that in The Treasury/IRD advice. I’ve seen people responding “ah well, didn’t matter, as he didn’t go ahead”. Donald Trump didn’t go ahead with most of his mad, bad, or evil schemes either, but that is slim consolation. We should expect better from someone who has been New Zealand’s Minister of Finance for 5.5 years.

But at this point the advice gets a whole lot worse, losing all touch with reality and descending into some spirit world of officials’ imagining. I’m including the entire section

One wonders if officials are able to opt out of this nonsense on grounds that no one should be forced to practice someone else’s religion. Do other worldviews count? I guess not, at least if this advice is to be taken seriously.

Or which of “our Treaty partners” were consulted on this highly sensitive matter of tax policy, even in a not very material way?

Or look at that footnote 87: a retrospective tax grab from four named foreign companies for purposes unrelated to anything to do with the activities of those companies would apparently “strengthen” “the human domain” (whatever that means). I suppose it would indeed have played to the “concept of power” – power in an arbitrary retrospective way, much more akin to an abusive act of attainder than anything. People would then have known the Minister (and his ministerial colleagues with him) as an unconstitutional thug.

In the end, Robertson didn’t proceed with his egregious scheme and for that small mercy we should be grateful. But we now know that ideas of such egregious grabs do play in his mind – not just an idle fancy, but weeks of work – and who knows when they might return, or which other company or individuals might then be in his sights. It wasn’t exactly Treasury at its best either.

UPDATE:

Meant to include this tweet

Flabbergasted

In the years after the financial crises of 2008/09 one often read plaintive cries of “and who went to prison?”, and angry claims that the system was rigged. I can’t say that I was ever much moved by such lines. We simply don’t – or shouldn’t – generally imprison people for being bad at the business they are in, whether it is banking or baking, even if the businesses themselves were big, and the people concerned had employers who’d previously paid them lots (and lots) of money.

There has been a plethora of books about aspects of that crisis period. Glancing along my bookshelves just now I counted 100 or more, most of which I’ve read. Some were very analytical, some were lively descriptions of some aspect or other of that period, some country-specific, some more general, some were more about policy and policy institutions, some more about bankers and financial markets, but not one of them disconcerted me (and that is putting it very mildly) in the way that Rigged, a new book by BBC economics correspondent Andrew Verity did. (Amazon Australia shows the publication date as 1 August 2023, but I ordered it and it arrived a few days ago). It is a simply astonishing story, which shows a whole set of authorities (notably the British ones) in a very very bad light.

The context is the so-called “LIBOR crisis”. For readers who followed that story over the last decade, much of what follows won’t be new, especially if you’ve been in the UK. But I hadn’t really, because it seemed to be mostly a moral/political panic, in the “why aren’t evil bankers in prison?” vein. And, to be honest, from what little I had read of the story, I knew that I’d observed stuff in the little New Zealand markets in my years in the Reserve Bank’s Financial Markets Department that, if you were concerned about this sort of thing, was arguably more egregious.

LIBOR is (or was) the “London Interbank Offer Rate” (there was also LIBID – “bid” – although I don’t think it gets a mention in the book). It was a major set of benchmark short term interest rates, in various currencies, off which many other contracts are priced. LIBOR rates were set each morning – under the auspices of the British Bankers’ Association (BBA) – when cash dealers in each of 16 banks would indicate (for each currency and term)

“At what rate could you borrow [unsecured] funds, were you to do so [in the London market] by asking for and then accepting inter-bank offers in a reasonable market size just prior to 11 am?”

The submissions would be ranked, with the top and bottom four excluded and the remaining eight averaged. Individual banks’ experiences could be expected to differ a bit (although not by much in normal times), and for any individual dealer answering the question there might be a (tightly-bunched) range of possibilities. It was an estimate, informed usually by data in fairly liquid markets, with the exclusion and averaging rules dealing with outliers and, thus, typically expected to result in a reasonable central estimate. Very short-term rates would typically be very close to the relevant central bank’s policy rate. Within each bank, there was often a bit of jockeying: other dealers might have positions that would benefit a little from that day’s LIBOR rate being just a bit higher or a bit lower, but since the cash dealer had to lodge a response at which his (they were almost all male at the time) bank could borrow, any leeway was apparently very slight, perhaps one basis point, occasionally two.

And so it had gone on for a couple of decades. Regulators knew how the system worked, the adminstrators (BBA) knew how the system worked, as did participants in the markets.

But then the financial crisis began to build in the second half of 2007 (the crisis period is often dated from 9 August that year, the Northern Rock crisis became public in early September 2007). Short-term interbank funding markets were no longer as liquid as they had been and material gaps started to open up between where banks would lend to each other unsecured and the central bank policy rates (either for fully collateralised lending or risk-free deposits at the central bank itself). And there were swirling differences in market and media perceptions of which banks might be a bit less sound than others.

You might have hoped that each bank’s dealer would simply continue to submit each day his best estimate of what his bank could borrow at unsecured and let things fall where they may. But that didn’t happen. Instead it became something of a “dirty secret” (except not very secret at all since people in banks and markets knew it, as did the key regulatory bodies, and there were even stories in the major financial newspapers) that the published LIBOR rates no longer represented a best estimate of what individual banks (or the sector as a whole) could borrow from each other at. Verity focuses in on Barclays, where the cash dealer seems to have tried quite vigorously to follow the rules, which resulted in Barclays posting rates above those of the rest of the panel of banks, which (submissions being visible to others) in turn prompted concerns “if they are having to pay that much they must be in more trouble”, and even a sell-off in the share price. And so the pressure came on the dealer from above to bring his submissions more into line with those of the other banks. He, rather grudgingly (documenting his concerns and uttering them to anyone who would listen), went along. Regulators and central banks on both sides of the Atlantic were aware of what was going on, and if anything seem to have been more sympathetic to Barclays than (say) concerned that posted rates (used as benchmark pricing across the system) no longer reflected real borrowing costs.

As the financial crisis intensified so did the problems (some quite practical, in that at times the markets had frozen so badly that really no bank could borrow unsecured from others, so in truth there probably should have been no LIBOR rate at all). The gaps between unsecured interbank rates (both “true” rates and published LIBOR rates) and policy rates was high and widening, at times when central banks – in the UK, but in most other countries – were cutting policy rates deeply to try to lean against the collapse in demand and economic activity. Market rates often weren’t coming down much (in some cases they were rising) and politicians and their advisers were often getting increasingly uneasy.

And so the pressure – and this is extremely well-documented in the book – came on banks to put in lower LIBOR submissions. Doing so wouldn’t change actual borrowing rates – either interbank or the retail rates that the wholesale rates influenced – but I guess it was going to get better headlines, and it might make it “look” like things (policy responses) were “working”. In the UK case (the focus of the book), this involved not just very senior figures at the Bank of England, but them channelling pressure from The Treasury and Downing St itself (people named include very senior and otherwise respected figures, including a current Deputy Governor of the Bank of England, and someone who was until last year the permanent head of The Treasury in the UK). Very senior bankers were left in no doubt that the authorities wanted the LIBOR rates marked down, and they complied, ordering their underlings (the cash dealers and their immediate bosses) to bring LIBOR submissions more into line. The differences here were not a matter of a basis point or two, but often 50 basis points or more. Relative to the LIBOR rules, anyone with a contract in which they received the LIBOR rate was, in effect, being bilked out of a lot of money (vice versa if you were paying LIBOR). One could, of course, argue, that central banks were actively trying to lower short-term rates generally by a lot, but…….acceptable instruments don’t generally include pressuring bankers to write down numbers that simply don’t reflect reality. If central banks really wanted market rates even lower, they had tools available to make that happen directly.

The more pragmatic and less idealistic of you may here be drumming your fingers and going “needs must”, and in a crisis what needs to be done gets done. I wouldn’t agree with you – institutions are supposed to be built for resilience under stress, not for fair weather events only – but if that was the end of the story, it would have been quickly lost to history.

But it wasn’t the end of the story.

As the crisis faded, in some circles the narrative that someone “needed to pay” took hold. At least in the UK, as I read the book, there wasn’t much interest in pursuing anything around LIBOR, until the Americans got involved. You might reasonably wonder what the activities of British officials in Britain and British employees of British banks in Britain, as regards a benchmark rate owned and administered by a British entity (the BBA) had to do with the US, and its Department of Justice and CFTC. They seem like good questions, but such is the world as it is, and the trans-national overreach of the US on matter financial. As Verity tells it, Obama’s nominee for head of the CFTC had had close ties to Wall St and wasn’t going to get confirmed by the Democrat-controlled Senate unless he was going to take a credible stance as an avenging angel of wrath.

My interest is less in the US side of things than in the UK, where (thanks to leaks in particular) the book is astonishingly well-documented. Anyway, the US started pursuing banks abroad (Barclays in particular in this book), in what seems like a bizarre process in which they relied on the banks themselves to search their own documents, and then negotiated (large) administrative fines, which saved the banks and their CEOs and chairs, all while throwing under the bus a few fairly junior employees who’d initially been more or less compelled to talk to the US authorities, thinking of themselves as expert witnesses etc, only to find themselves personally in the gun,

These employees became alert to the prospect of spending much of the rest of their lives in a US prison, (having regard to the very low acquittal rate in US courts) for things they were quite sure they had never done, except as normal, accepted commercial practice, well known to central banks and regulatory agencies on both sides of the Atlantic, typically either authorised or instructed by senior managers within their own banks. And so several became convinced their only option was to get themselves charged in the UK, preferably engaging in a plea deal that might involve, to all intents and purposes, lying to conform with the preferred narrative of the UK authorities, to get to stay in the UK and not destroy themselves and their families financially. Others preferred to defend themselves in the UK, several were charged in the US (before US courts finally overturned the very basis on which they had been charged).

And, to be quite clear here, none of all this regulatory and legal action involved anything that had gone on during the financial crisis (when not only had authorities, notably the Bank of England, been aware of how the system worked, they had actually been part of engineering LIBOR submissions a long way from actual market rates). Instead, the bounds of interest were very carefully drawn to cover only the period prior to the crisis beginning to unfold. The focus was on how these dealers had lodged their LIBOR submissions in normal times, as many many like them had done for a couple of decades. The focus was on other people in each bank suggesting to the dealer that their positions might benefit from a slightly higher or slightly lower LIBOR (the basis point or two mentioned above, in reaching a necessarily imprecise estimate).

And what was the offence? Well, there was none in statutory law. None.

Instead, the authorities wheeled out an old common law offence “conspiracy to defraud”, which – at least as Verity tells it – was so little regarded by the UK commercial barristers prior to the crisis that there had been a push to remove it. Under these provisions/precedents, there was no need to show that anyone had lost, or to quantify any losses. And yet the political rhetoric was all about egregious rip-offs, suffering customers, and rigged markets. Judges ruled – without allowing appeal – that it was enough that someone in a bank had suggested to the bank’s cash dealer that his/her positions might benefit from a slightly lower/higher LIBOR and the dealer to say something like he’d see what he could do. There was – according to English justice- a conspiracy to defraud – all recorded in emails and trading room recorded phone calls. The same judges then refused to allow testimony from expert witnesses as to how markets actually worked (in one case regarding EURIBOR submissions, the UK judge refused to allow testimony from the people who had written the code of conduct around the operation of EURIBOR).

Here, some scale and perspective is worth noting. As I noted above, LIBOR worked with a panel of 16 banks, with the four highest and four lowest for any particular currency/term on the day excluded. If perhaps a dealer in one bank had shaded his bank’s estimates 1 basis point in one direction (remember that plausible range was typically not much more than a couple of basis points), then even assuming there was not some other bank with exactly the opposite interest, the chance of affecting LIBOR at all was low, and the magnitude of any plausible effect tiny. There are hard numbers at places in the book.

By contrast, the activities during the financial crisis period, done in full awareness and often with the encouragement of the authorities and of specific named very senior bankers, never saw judicial scrutiny.

And so eight bankers – cash dealers – went to prison in the UK, serving non-trivial custodial sentences, for offences that no one thought were offences until the “avenging angel” mood took hold in the wake of the crisis. And when I say “no one” here I mean not just the dealers, but their bosses, their bosses’ bosses (the chief executives of the banks were the board of the BBA which administered LIBOR), and the central banks and regulatory authorities on both sides of the Atlantic, but particularly (and at very senior levels) the Bank of England. Not one Bank of England official rang the police (or SFO) at any point to express concern at the normal commercial way they knew the market worked, and those senior people are on record during the crisis encouraging/abetting/ (perhaps) instructing, bankers to deviate from the LIBOR rules, including passing on the political pressure from Downing St (which was no part of any central banker’s mandate).

And yet, as Verity records, in 2015 at the height of the hysteria – and amid the criminal trials – the then Governor of the Bank of England delivered a major speech in which he would “publicly demand that the government should change its sentencing guidelines to raise the maximum jail term for “rogue traders” from seven to ten years”. This was (is) the same central bank that (Verity records) “George Osborne had urged the central bank to come clean about its role in Libor, [but] the Bank of England had decided against that. Freedom of Information requests would be consistently rejected in the succeeding years”.

Your reaction might be to wonder why anyone would be particularly sympathetic to well paid (not very senior) bank traders. Because it was an egregious abuse of justice: sound process and integrity matter whether it is a scruffy teenager or a nicely-dressed multi-millionaire trader facing the system. Any of us could one day be in gunsights of the state. I mean, if one were going to (in effect) create retrospective offences and start prosecuting bankers for them mightn’t one prosecute those in charge (all the way up) who were actively aware of how things worked, authorised and rewarded people, and at times directly instructed behaviour that was egregiously distortive (in terms of LIBOR rules/practices (rather than, as in at least one case a ‘whistleblower’), and consider expert testimony from people with responsibility for overseeing the relevant markets etc.

The conduct of three lots of people in this whole affair warrant scrutiny:

  • the politicians.   How did Cabinet ministers stand by and allow these prosecutions and imprisonments when (if nothing else) they knew the people who managed and instructed those charged walked free, with no criminal or civil consequences whatever?   And how did former PMs and Cabinet ministers (Gordon Brown, Alistair Darling –  Chancellor during the crisis) never speak up and out, not just about their own roles but the disproportion of sending low level people to prison while their bosses walked free?  It is the sort of act of omission that leads people to simply despise politicians,
  • the senior bankers.  Many despise them already, but really……..you keep your job and your bank or walk way with tens of millions in retirement packages etc, while seeing former staff – who acted on your instruction and authorisation – sent to prison, people against whom charges were laid only because you did your own searches of your own bank records, saved yourself, and tossed some staff to the criminal authorities.  Just despicable.   Who ordered Peter Johnson (cash dealer at Barclays) to mark down his submissions, despite Johnson’s explicit written dissent?  Why, the very top tier of Barclays’ management.
  • the central bankers (and the like).  I expect better from central bank and Treasury officials.  Not necessarily excellence or at times even basic competence, but integrity and decency.   I’ve met and dealt with some of the individuals named (I recall now sitting in the Bank of England’s chief economists’ seminar in May 2008, in the early days of the crisis, listening to Sir John Gieve, deputy governor responsible for financial stability – altho, curiously, not named in the book) so perhaps it shocks me more.   Perhaps one can defend the approaches senior BoE or HMT (or even Downing St) officials took during the crisis, but they actively aided (and seem to have pressured banks to facilitate) the distortion of LIBOR.  I’m not suggesting any of them should have been prosecuted, but how (a) does the Bank of England justify not revealing in full its own part and knowledge during the period, all while Mark Carney as Governor was baying for the blood of traders, and b) how come that, even in retirement, not one of these people spoke out and suggested that it was simply wrong to be sending these people to prison.   None of them appears to have been willing to speak to Verity, none has spoken in public, and we are left guess whether just possibly one or two might have said quietly “I say old chap, are we really sure about this?” (if so, to no apparent effect).  It reflects very poorly on all involved, some of the most senior (and otherwise) respected figures in British economic and financial policy.  One could see it – perhaps unfairly but it isn’t obvious what other interpretation makes sense – as circling the wagons in their own defence, and that of their peers who ran the banks.  Never mind the juniors, we can destroy their lives and marriages and send them to prison.   (These the same people whose own policy misjudgments –  viz recent inflation (Andrew Bailey gets a couple of minor mentions in the book) – result in few/no consequences beyond gilded retirements and knighthoods or peerages.)

From the sound of the book, the English prosecutorial and judicial systems have quite a bit to answer for as well, but….I’ll leave that to the lawyers.

The whole thing smacks of a witchhunt: someone must pay, these individuals their bosses have helpfullly pointed us to are someones, so they will do (and it wouldn’t do to pursue the bosses or else, perhaps, confidence in the system might be eroded –  which if true should have at very least raised questions as to whether the whole grossly-slanted chain of prosecutions, where eg juries were never allowed to know what regulators had known in advance, was being pursued for any reason other than the a politically-driven effort at distraction).

It is hard to tell if I’ve done a 325 page book justice.  All I can do is to encourage people to read it.  Yes, it is about technical stuff, but Verity does an impressive job of explanation and translation, and his story is supported with copious direct quotations, most of which would never have come to public light if a big dump of documents and recording had not been leaked to him.  I’m going to leave you with the Amazon review comments of Sarah Tighe, herself a lawyer, ex-wife of one of those sent to prison (there is a recent extended interview with him here)

tighe

I went looking for reviews of the book, and couldn’t yet find any yet. But interest in the issue seems to be rising again in the UK (here is a recent parliamentary speech from a senior backbencher).

One fears that even if the individuals eventually have their convictions overturned (and how do you compensate someone for a life destroyed?) that officialdom in particular will never have to answer the hard questions it seems it (collectively and as accountable individuals) should.

PS Someone who isn’t named in the book, but the division he ran is, is the Reserve Bank’s Deputy Governor whose CV includes this

Now that was probably a fourth [UPDATE: or perhaps 5th1] tier position in the Bank of England, and he took this specific position up just after the worst, so he wouldn’t have been in any sort of direct decision-making role. But one is left wondering how he feels about those sent to prison while he’d been a fairly senior part of a system and institution that was encouraging banks actively to manipulate LIBOR submissions/rates. It should matter in someone who is (a) on the MPC, b) is head of financial stability here, and c) must be one of the favourites to himself be the next Governor of the Reserve Bank. There is that old line “the standard you walk by is the standard you accept”. No one should accept – or walk by – the standards of officialdom on display in this book.

  1. See references to Hawkesby in footnotes to the organisation chart on page 60 of this later BoE report

An external MPC member speaks

This blog has been a bit quiet in recent weeks (if anyone has insights on what sections 15D and 98 of the Government Superannuation Fund Act do and don’t allow I’ll be happy to hear from you) but I hope to make up for it this week.

In the 4+ years the statutory Monetary Policy Committee has been in existence, there has been not a single public speech given by any of the three external members. There have been no serious interviews either, just one petulant and testy set of responses to some emailed questions late last year, responses that I characterised at the time this way:

At times, Harris displays all the grace and constructive open and engagement we might expect in a rebellious 15 year old told they have to make conversation with Grandma at the family Christmas celebrations. If the answers aren’t quite monosyllabic grunts. most of them might as well be.

There have never been any rules against external MPC members speaking, just some mix of the Governor’s wishes and their own predilections (shy, lacking confidence in their own views, reluctant to face scrutiny, or simply not believing in either openness or accountability?) that meant it never happened. It really was quite astonishing: not only was it a new regime, which one might have thought participants might have wanted to show off at the best it could be, but we then went into a period of turmoil and fairly extreme policy experimentation, quickly followed by……the biggest monetary policy failure in decades (that high and persistent core inflation), as well as $10 billion of financial losses, for which the taxpayer (you and me) were on the hook. Surely any decent person, charged with all the power and responsibility they personally took the taxpayer’s dime to assume, would want to explain their thinking, their mistakes, and the lessons they’d individually learned.

But not Harris, Buckle, and Saunders, all three now limping towards the end of ill-starred terms in office (each having been reappointed once, they can’t be appointed again – Harris and Saunders will be gone by this time next year, and Buckle by early the following year). And we know nothing at about their views, their contributions, their defences, the lessons they’ve learned, or even any contrition they might feel. Of that latter, presumably none or surely they’d have told us. Decent journalists are only an email or phone call away. Meanwhile, we live with the inflation, the looming recession…..oh, and as taxpayers are $10 billion poorer as a result of their choices.

You’ll remember that the external members were selected in a process whereby (in the words of a Treasury paper to the Minister of Finance)

Which did tend to select against people who might either think hard or make serious and self-critical attempts to learn from their mistakes.

You may also remember a strange article a few weeks ago in which the Minister of Finance and The Treasury (but not the Bank or the Bank’s Board) tried to pretend that there had never been any such restriction. A couple of us are still waiting for responses to OIA to better make sense of quite what game Treasury and the Minister were playing there, but my post a few weeks back makes clear – from their own contemporaneous words at several points through the process- that there had in fact been such a restriction. It appears to have been removed for the next round of MPC appointments (vacancies being advertised at present), and if so that is a welcome step forward.

And somehow, one of the external members, (emeritus professor) Bob Buckle, emerged from his monetary policy purdah to deliver a keynote lecture at the recent conference of the New Zealand Association of Economists (invited, he tells us, by the council of the NZAE no less). His topic? “Monetary policy and the benefits and limits of central bank independence”.

There is 25 pages of text and more than 150 references at the end. But here’s the thing. I’m pretty sure I learned nothing from the lecture and wasn’t prompted to think harder or differently about anything.

In a way, perhaps that isn’t surprising. Buckle’s focus has tended to be on empirical macro (VAR models and all that) and some public finance and tax issues. He doesn’t have a publication record in areas around central bank independence, and has not (that I’m aware of) offered any speeches, presentation, papers or anything with interesting or challenging angles on the issue over the course of his academic career. He is, in many respects, a pleasant establishment figure (and there is a place for them) not one who will make you think about things freshly or differently.

Perhaps the council of the Association of Economists was thinking, “well, after four turbulent years as a foundation member of a Monetary Policy Committee perhaps he will offering some perspectives informed by his experience as a policymaker. After all, he done no speeches, but this will be a more academic audience, which might be in his comfort zone. And, after all, a lot hasn’t gone well for monetary policy in the last few years”. If so, they must have been disappointed.

Someone who was there sent me a message later that day

I’m no expert so cannot speak about the literature he described, but the lack of NZ content was so noticeable it was weird. Cliches about “elephant in the room” and all that. He did mention “we need to wait for full assessment” when someone asked a question about the covid monetary interventions, but he was obviously uncomfortable saying even that.

It seemed impossible to distinguish from a paper he might have written had he never been appointed to the MPC. Was there nothing he thought differently about, or understand more (or less) from having been inside the tent? If so, he clearly wasn’t inclined to tell us. And, in fact, as my correspondent pointed out there was hardly anything about New Zealand at all (I checked and there are no mentions of “New Zealand” outside footnotes and references that are more recent than about 1990).

It can’t have been just that he didn’t want to offer any thoughts relevant to the immediate monetary policy situation (where will the OCR peak and when and why?). It must instead have been that he had nothing insightful or challenging to say on his own topic (just possibly, the Governor had persuaded him to deliver something so grey and un-insightful, but (a) that would hardly be in the Governor’s interest (he is usually keen to talk up his committee), and (b) real insight shines through anyway. There was none in Buckle’s paper.

There might, for example, have been thoughts on accountability. The literature is replete with references to the importance of accountability if a central bank is to have operational autonomy. But how does Buckle think about that specifically, having been one of those who were to be (in principle) held to account, in tough times. What sort of accountability does he think really matters and why? What, if anything, made a difference to his own conduct/advice. He offers us nothing.

Or, say, on communications. What is it that convinced Buckle, now as a policymaker, that never hearing from (ostensibly) powerful key policymakers (and it isn’t just no speeches or no interviews but no select committee appearances) is the best way to run an operationally independent central bank? Again, no insight.

And if operational independence for central banks tends to reduce inflation (there is some suggestion in the literature that it may), is that always and everywhere a good thing. After all, in the aftermath of 2008/09, a whole bunch of countries went through a protracted period of inflation undershooting the target. Perhaps an inflation-happy Minister of Finance might then have been better than an independent central bank? Perhaps not, but the issue isn’t addressed (not even, more extremely, in the Japanese context). And on the other side, there is no serious engagement – even slightly speculative – on what the experiences of the last few years tell us about the case for central bank independence? The implied promise 30 years ago was that if we handed over day to day control to central bankers, we wouldn’t see core inflation of 5-7 per cent again. And yet we did. Buckle never engages much with Tucker’s criteria for delegation to expert agencies (either for central banks, or by comparison with other government activities), but it isn’t controversial that the case for delegation is stronger, all else equal, when the delegatee knows what it is doing.

There is nothing at all about whether, and if not why not, it might be important to buttressing central bank monetary policy operational independence to do something about fixing the effective lower bound on nominal interest rates.

There isn’t even any sense of an intuitive familiarity with the experiences of other countries. What, if anything, do we learn from the cases of the (very small handful) of advanced countries that hadn’t given independence to their central banks (low inflation Singapore being a prime example). These aren’t just issues for New Zealand, but he is a (retired) New Zealand academic and a New Zealand policymaker.

And so on.

There were various small things I took exception to. There were hints of Orr (misleading Parliament) in a couple of attempts to shed some of the blame for inflation onto the Russians, as if core inflation had not already reached its peak (and unemployment its trough) before that invasion

There was the somewhat surprising claim

That footnote 50 took you, among other places for other countries, to the Reserve Bank’s report marking its own homework late last year. Sure enough, when you check it the word “mistake” doesn’t appear at all (or “error”) and there is no expression of “regret” at all (you’ll recall Orr’s standard line is the non-regret regret “I regret that NZ has had to deal with a pandemic, the war etc”).

And if this paper might not have been the place to go into all that in detail, wasn’t it an obvious place to think aloud about the place for contrition (people being human, mistakes being inevitably, and some of those mistakes are very costly indeed to people who are not themselves policymakers, while often appearing to have no consequences at all for those who made the mistake) in the independence/accountability context.

One interesting line that popped up in several places during the speech was a concern about anything that might tie the hands of the MPC.

This paper suggests there are intersections between legislated objectives and operational independence that could have implications for central bank independence and the political acceptability of CBI. These intersections involve expanding central bank mandates, conditions attached to the pursuit of primary objectives of monetary policy, and funding arrangements that could influence central bank independence over the choice and scope of alternative monetary policy instruments.

That is fairly wordy, but what it means is that Buckle thinks they need to be free to lose $10 billion again on fresh highly risky financial interventions (having neither here nor in the 2022 self-review either expressed contrition for the actual losses, shown how they would do better in future, or explored whether there might be reasonable limits to the financial losses taxpayers might be willing to let unelected officials incur (almost all government spending has to be appropriated by Parliament first, but not when the MPC takes the public balance sheet for a spin)).

Which brings me nicely to the last substantive section of Buckle’s paper, on fiscal policy connections. It is fairly unenlightening (and reminded me of the ambitious play by the Secretary to the Treasury for a greater role for fiscal policy just before everything went to pot on inflation). But Buckle repeats, unreflectively, suggestions that central bank independence might have led to lower fiscal deficits (and seems to think this is automatically a good thing). He then suggests that times are changing and fiscal policy might be more of a threat, illustrated with this chart

Perhaps, but here is another way of looking at things. Here is net government debt for half a dozen small to middling inflation targeters with independent central banks, including New Zealand

All these countries have pretty moderate levels of net debt, and all except Australia (barely) have had a falling ratio of net government liabilities to GDP over the last 30 years.

On the other hand, here are some other (larger) countries with independent central banks (in the euro area by far the most independent of any of the central banks)

All four lines slope upwards, and in all four cases debt is a lot higher than it was in 1995, early in the new era of central bank independence.

Perhaps it is fair to suggest there may be some future issues in some of these countries for central banks, but you’d have thought that a New Zealand policymaker might recognise the very wide range of country experiences (which might also make one a little sceptical that whether or not the central bank is independent explains much if anything of advanced country fiscal choices and outcomes).

No doubt there will have been some readers who got something from something like the Buckle lecture (I passed it on to my economics student son eg, and there is always a use for introductory material), but from a serving policy maker, to a premier New Zealand economics audience, it really is pretty disappointing.

Buckle is probably the least unqualified of the external MPC members, but efforts like this are a reminder of how far from the frontier of best practice New Zealand’s new MPC – creature of Orr, Quigley, and Robertson – is. One can only hope that if there is a new government that they will care enough to insist on much better (in the RB, and in so many of New Zealand’s degraded public sector institutions)>