A BNZ economist and the powers that be

No, not Stephen Toplis.

This is a story about an earlier BNZ Chief Economist, Len Bayliss.   A commenter on my post on Graeme Wheeler’s attempt to silence Stephen Toplis reminded me of how Bayliss’s career at the BNZ ended, victim of intense pressure from the then Prime Minister and Minister of Finance, Robert Muldoon, and a pusillanimous Board and management of what was then a wholly government-owned bank.

Len Bayliss was one of New Zealand’s leading, and most prominent, economists from the 1960s to the 1980s, particularly as the BNZ’s chief economist for 15 years or so.   A few years ago I did an interview about his career with him for the newsletter of the New Zealand Association of Economists.   As he records it, that interview and some follow-up questions from me prompted him to put together a volume of documents and recollections  –  Recollections: Bank of New Zealand 1981-1992  – dealing with his ouster from the BNZ and his later term as a government-appointed director of the BNZ as it descended into crisis and near-failure in the late 1980s and early 1990s.   I’m fortunate enough to have a copy.

Bayliss and Muldoon had, at one time, worked very closely together, with Bayliss having served as a member of the Advisory Group in the Prime Minister’s Department when National returned to office at the end of 1975.  A lot of financial liberalisation went on over the following couple of years, and Bayliss appears (there are conflicting accounts, but I’ve found Bayliss’s persuasive) to have played a key role in that.

Decades on, in that interview I did with him, Bayliss could still record of Muldoon

Excellent. He was the best boss I’ve ever had. Absolutely decisive. I wrote his speech for the Mansion House dinner, the most important speech he’d made after becoming PM. I gave it to him. He said send it to Treasury and see if it’s all right with them. They wrote back wanting something changed and wrote a little memo and he just put ‘No’. And he always was very proper. He may have been tough to his political opponents but as Bernard Galvin used to say, certainly in the time I was there, it was a very happy group. He never tried to force you to do anything. In a sense, he treated you just like a public servant, as a politician should treat them. He was decisive. He would argue very intelligently. Watching him at the Cabinet Economic Committee, he really tore strips off ministers who hadn’t done their homework. And I saw him several times in debates with Noel Lough [senior Treasury official]. Noel Lough was a lovely bloke but Muldoon really won the debates.

But after Bayliss’s return to the BNZ, and as New Zealand’s economic difficulties became increasingly apparent –  with Bayliss among those openly highlighting the issues – the sentiments certainly weren’t reciprocated.

The crisis began to come to a head after Bayliss was interviewed on Radio New Zealand’s Morning Report on 14 August 1981.   After a lengthy introduction, setting the scene for a discussion of the value of the exchange rate, the presenter turned to Bayliss

Bayliss:    I think we have to do a number of things.  We have to change the exchange rate, we’ve got to get our budget deficit reduced, we’ve got to get better control of the money supply and we’ve got to replace import controls by tariffs, and we’ve got to get more competition into the economy.

Reporter: Well, you’re talking about the exchange rate. You’re talking devaluation are you?

Bayliss: That would be it, yes.

The interview went on, concluding thus

Reporter:  Well, this artificially high value of our currency has been held for many years I mean its not a recent thing. You know, why do we keep on doing it?

Bayliss:  I think the reason we keep on with it is two-fold.  First of all if you just devalue and do nothing else….you get a very short-term gain and in six months’ time the rate of inflation is worse. I think the second reason is that we’ve built up a system in New Zealand where a large number of industries and sectors and firms and so on are subsidised and naturally these people fight hard to maintain their subsidies……. The New Zealand economy has had nil rates of growth for about five years and rising levels of unemployment and this is a pretty deplorable economic performance……If we are going to improve our economic performance then we have to make some pretty dramatic changes in economic policy.

The Prime Minister was not happy at all.   That shouldn’t have surprised anyone –  who likes have their approach openly criticised?  But the Prime Minister didn’t just complain to his colleagues, thump the desk, and get on with his day.  Instead, he wrote a letter to the chairman of the Board of the BNZ.  News of this letter got out  –  it took a while –  and on 15 October there was parliamentary question about it.  Answering on behalf of the Prime Minister, Jim Bolger stated

“I wrote to the Chairman of the Bank of New Zealand on 25 August 1981 expressing concern that Mr Bayliss’s comments were not only misleading and not factually based, but that they would also have an adverse effect on our international credit.  Both the management and the Chairman of the bank have told me they regretted Mr Bayliss’s comments”

Opposition MP Stan Rodger then asked

“Can this be taken as as indication that the Government is adverse to having open debate in society within the news media on economic developments and on economic factors affecting New Zealand society?”

Bolger:  “No it most certainly cannot be taken as an indication that we do not welcome public debate on issues.  The question that was posed is whether or not the issue that was being debated was being debated factually, whether it was being debated in a manner that would not be harmful to New Zealand.  As the answer was written by the Prime Minister, it was his belief that the NZ comments would affect New Zealand’s international credit.  That is something that is of some moment.”

Another Labour MP, Michael Bassett continued

“When the Prime Minister wrote to the Bank of New Zealand was it his intention to silence Mr Bayliss altogether, or was it simply to ensure that he debated the economy on terms that were agreeable to the Prime Minister?”

Bolger:  I cannot answer the question in the way it was posed because I do not know the precise intention of the Prime Minister when he wrote the letter. However, I am sure the Prime Minister will welcome debate on this issue or any other based on facts, not on any other basis.”

At the next meeting on the BNZ Board, (according to a contemporary file note) the Board apparently spent “considerable time discussing public statements on economic matters by the Chief Economist – in particular forthcoming speech to Hutt Chamber of Commerce”.    The chief executive informed Bayliss that “in future contents of any public statement on economy by Chief Economist should be such that they provoke no criticism whatsoever by Prime Minister.”

Bayliss responded (again, according to the file note) “impossible to make accurate, balanced and professional analysis of economy under such criteria –  a view which would be shared by all economists and many others. Board placing Chief Economist in impossible position –  best to cancel speech.”

To which the chief executive is recorded as responding “Can’t do that –  must make speech. Cancellation would damage image of BNZ and provoke public questioning of Board’s attitude. Only consideration must be BNZ’s public reputation.”

And so it went on in subsequent days.   Bayliss eventually informed that BNZ that under these conditions he would probably feel obliged to resign, and did so early the following year.   Both the Board of the BNZ and the Prime Minister disavowed any responsibility.

Bayliss includes in his collection of documents, a letter he received shortly after his resignation from John Stone, then the Secretary to the Treasury in Australia (and still vigorously contributing to the debate in Australia in his late 80s).  Stone wrote

“I learned yesterday of the announcement of your impending resignation from your present position with the Bank of New Zealand.  The reports which I saw of that development were naturally only of a general kind – the suggestion being that there had been some reaction from the political heights to the outspokennes and straight-speaking on the New Zealand economy which over recent years you have become well (and let me emphasise favourably) known.

“Whether or not there is truth in those kinds of speculation I naturally do not know. If there were I would think it is a sad reflection upon a country for which as you know I retain a considerable affection.

Indeed.

Graeme Wheeler was a junior Treasury official in late 1981. I wonder what he made of Muldoon’s attack on Bayliss?  Did he even imagine that one day he’d be writing to the BNZ to complain of another economist whose style and/or substance had offended him, as high public servant and powerful regulator?  Surely not.

 

 

Two sides of the same coin

When, a couple of months ago, the current National-led government announced plans to tighten immigration policy in several areas, I summed up the changes as “a modest step that ignores the big picture“.

Yesterday, the Labour Party announced the immigration policy it will campaign on.  I’d use exactly the same words to describe their proposals.  Some of the changes –  the largest ones –  seem broadly sensible, but they won’t come close to tackling the real problems with New Zealand’s immigration policy.

In some ways the biggest difference between the two parties’ approaches is that National provided us with no estimates about what impact their changes would have on numbers (and the Prime Minister apparently claimed yesterday they would,  in fact, have no impact on numbers), while Labour is touting large numerical impacts but not acknowledging that they will actually have little or no medium to long-term effect on the net inflows of non-New Zealand citizens.

In many ways, none of this should be a surprise.  The “big New Zealand” strategy, revitalised over the last 25 years, has been a bipartisan project.   On either party’s policy, it remains one.   There is really no material difference between them –  just details which, while not unimportant, don’t affect the underlying strategy.  A strategy which, to the extent it had an economic performance objective behind it (recall how MBIE used to call our immigration policy, “a critical economic enabler”), has simply failed.  There is no reason to expect anything much better if future if we keep on with the same policies.

What determines the medium-term contribution of immigration policy to population growth is the residence programme, which aims to give out around 45000 residence approvals each year.  The government cut that target a little last year.  Labour’s policy doesn’t even mention it.   At 45000 approvals, the programme is roughly three times the size, in per capita terms, of the equivalent programme is the United States (where about one million green cards are issued each year).

But what of the proposals Labour did put forward.  Their policy document is here.   It is misconceived from the first sentences where they state

Migrants bring to New Zealand the skills we need to grow our economy

Have they not seen the OECD data showing that New Zealanders are among the most highly-skilled people in the advanced world, and that –  on average –  immigrants are a bit less skilled than natives?    On the scale the New Zealand immigration programme attempts to operate at, the typical new additions to the labour force from non-citizen migration are not as highly skilled as the people who are already here, and our own young people who enter, and move up in, the workforce each year.   There are, of course, no doubt some exceptionally talented people.   But most are people from poorer countries looking for better opportunities here for themselves and their families –  typically, too, people who couldn’t get into the richer and more successful Anglo countries.  (None of this is a criticism of the migrants –  pursing the best for themselves and their families is probably what all of us seek to do too – but it is a criticism of the policy framework that enables such large inflows of not overly-skilled people.)

Mostly Labour’s policy seems to be about fixing some pretty dubious changes made to the student visa system over recent years.   In fact, three-quarters of the total numerical impact of their policy comes (on their own numbers) from student visa changes.

Labour will stop issuing student visas for courses below a bachelor’s degree which are not independently assessed by the TEC and NZQA to be of high quality.

Labour will also limit the ability to work while studying to international students studying at Bachelor-level or higher. For those below that level, their course will have to have the ability to work approved as part of the course.

Labour will limit the “Post Study Work Visa – Open” after graduating from a course of study in New Zealand to those who have studied at Bachelor-level or higher.

Mostly, those seem like a broadly sensible direction of change.   That said, I’m slightly uneasy about relying on bureaucratic agencies to decide whether courses are “high quality” –  in principle, surely the market can take care of reputational and branding issues?

And while it might look good on paper, I’m a little uneasy about the line drawn between bachelor’s degree and other lines of study.  It seems to prioritise more academic courses of study over more vocational ones, and while the former will often require a higher level of skill, the potential for the system to be gamed, and for smart tertiary operators to further degrade some of the quality of their (very numerous) bachelor’s degree offerings can’t be ignored.  In the student visa data we already see some slightly suspicious signs (bottom right chart) of switching from PTEs to universities  I’d probably have been happier if the right to work while studying had been withdrawn, or more tightly limited, for all courses.   And if open post-study work visas had been restricted to those completing post-graduate qualifications.

Selling education to foreign students is an export industry, and tighter rules will (on Labour’s own numbers) mean a reduction in the total sales of that industry.   Does that bother me?  No, not really.  When you subsidise an activity you tend to get more of it.  We saw that with subsidies to manufacturing exporters in the 1970s and 80s, and with subsidies to farmers at around the same time.  We see it with film subsidies today.  Export incentives simply distort the economy, and leave us with lower levels of productivity, and wealth/income, than we would otherwise have.   In export education, we haven’t been giving out government cash with the export sales, but the work rights (during study and post-study) and the preferential access to points in applying for residence are subsidies nonetheless.  If the industry can stand on its own feet, with good quality educational offerings pitched at a price the market can stand, then good luck to it.  If not, we shouldn’t be wanting it here any more than we want car assembly plants or TV manufacturing operations here.

Labour estimates that their changes to student visas and post-work study visas will reduce numbers by around 17000, roughly evenly split between the two classes of changes.  But what they don’t tell you is that these will be one-off reductions in the total number of people here on those visas.    Since the number of people who settle here permanently is determined by the residence approvals programme, and that hasn’t changed, the changes Labour is promising around student visas –  while broadly sensible –  while make a difference to the net migration flow in the first year they are implemented (the transition to the lower stock level) and none at all thereafter.   They might change, a little, who ends up with a residence visa, but not how many are issued.  If you favour high levels of non-citizen immigration but just want the “rorts” tidied up, it makes quite a lot of sense.

The changes Labour proposes to work visas are also something of a mixed bag.  They are promising (but with few/no specifics) to make it harder for people to get work visas

Since 2011/12, the number of low-skill (ANZSCO 4 and 5) work visas issued has surged from 14,000 to 22,000. For example, the number of “retail supervisor” work visas has increased from 700 to 1,700. Labour will work with firms to train New Zealanders to fill skills gaps so we don’t have to permanently rely on immigration. A developed nation should be able to train enough retail staff to meet its own needs. Immigration should be a stop-gap to meet skills shortages, not a permanent crutch.

Labour will make changes that preserve and enhance the ability of businesses to get skilled workers to fill real skills gaps but which prevent the abuses of the system that currently happen.

The broad direction seems sensible enough –  after all, the official rhetoric about the gains from immigration relate to really highly-skilled people, but what does it mean specifically?

And I get much more wary about proposals to move to a more regional approach (on top of the additional points for regional jobs the government introduced last year, thus further reducing the skill level of the average migrant).  This is what they say:

Currently, few skill shortages are regionalised. This makes it hard for a region with a skills shortage in a specific occupation to get on the list if the shortage is not nationwide. Importantly it means that work visas are issued for jobs in regions where there is not actually a shortage which puts unnecessary pressures on housing and transport infrastructure there.

Labour’s regionalised system will work with local councils, unions and business to determine where shortages exist and will require that skilled immigrants work in the region that their visa is issued for. This will prevent skills shortages in one region being used to justify work visas in another, while also making it easier for regions with specific needs to have those skills shortages met.

Where skills shortages are identified, Labour will develop training plans with Industry Training Organisations so that the need for skilled workers is met domestically in the long-term. We will invest in training through Dole for Apprenticeships and Three Years Fees Free policies.

Frankly, it seems like a bureaucrat’s paradise, and just the thing for influential business groups that get the ear of some local council or other.  It is hard enough to ensure that local authorities operate in the interests of their people, without setting up more incentives that will allow local authorities to be used to pursue the interests of one particular class of voters.

More generally, it is an approach that suggests no confidence at all in market mechanisms to deal with incipient labour market pressures.  There is no suggestion in the document, at all, that higher wages might be a natural adjustment mechanism, whether to deal with increased demand in a particular region or for a particular set of skills.  Even the Prime Minister was running that line recently  –  and he isn’t from the party supported by the union movement.

Again, changes to reduce the number of work visas granted to people for fairly low-skilled occupations aren’t a bad thing, but they won’t make any difference to the average net inflow of non New Zealanders beyond the initial (quite small) one-off level adjustment.     And there is no willingness to rely on market mechanisms –  eg set a (say) $15000 per annum fee, and allow limited work visas for jobs where the employer is willing to pay the taxpayer that additional price.

There were two other initiatives in the package.  The first was the proposed new Exceptional Skills visa.

Labour will introduce an Exceptional Skills Visa. This visa will enable people with exceptional skills and talents that will enrich New Zealand society — not just its economy — to gain residency here. 

It will be available to people who can show they are in an occupation on the long-terms skills list and have significant experience or qualifications beyond that required (for example, experienced paediatric oncologist) or are internationally renowned for their skills or talents. Successful applicants will avoid the usual points system requirements for a Skilled Migrant Category visa and would be able to bring their partner and children within the visa. This visa will help grow high-tech new industries, meet the increasingly complex needs of the 21st Century and enrich our society. Exceptional Skills Visas for up to 1,000 people, including partners and children, will be offered every year

When I first saw reference to this I was quite encouraged.  And if it makes a little easier for people who are genuinely highly-skilled to get first claim on those 45000 residence approvals each year, then I don’t have any problem with it.   But it isn’t exactly the American exceptional ability visa, and we need to be realistic about New Zealand’s relative attractiveness (or lack of it) to people with really exceptional talents.   The suggestion that the programme will “help growth high-tech new industries, meet the increasingly complex needs of the 21st century” is probably little more than late 20th century vapourware.

As for the proposed KiwiBuild visas, I suppose they were politically necessary. You leave yourself open if you campaign on both big reductions in migrant numbers, and massive increases in house-building, if you don’t prioritise construction workers.  In fact, of course, this programme makes a one-off reduction in the number of people here –  reductions concentrated in the population group that probably has the least housing needs..  None of the medium-term pressures will have been eased at all, even if some dodgy rules around students do end tightened.

In passing, I was also interested in this comment

We will investigate ways to ensure that the Pacific Access Quota and Samoan Quota which are currently underutilised are fully met.

I guess there are really large numbers of Pacific voters in Labour’s South Auckland heartland.    These Pacific quotas, again, lower the average skill level of those we given residence approval too (since people only come in on those quotas if they can’t qualify otherwise, all within the 45000 approvals per annum total).  I imagine, too, that the Australian High Commission will have taken note of that line.

Overall, some interesting steps, some of which are genuinely in the right direction.  But, like the government, Labour is still in the thrall of the “big New Zealand” mentality, and its immigration policy –  like the government’s – remain this generation’s version of Think Big.  And it is just as damaging.    The policy doesn’t face up to the symptoms of our longer-term economic underperformance –  the feeble productivity growth, the persistently high real interest and exchange rates, the failure to see market-led exports growing as a share of GDP, and the constraints of extreme distance.  None of those suggest it makes any sense to keep running one here of the large non-citizen immigration programmes anywhere in the world, pulling in lots of new people year after year, even as decade after decade we drift slowly further behind other advanced countries, and se the opportunities for our own very able people deteriorate.

But that is Labour’s policy.  And that is National’s policy.

For anyone interested, the Law and Economics Association is hosting a seminar on immigration policy and economic performance on Monday evening 26 June.   Eric Crampton of the New Zealand Initiative and I will be speaking.  Details are here.

UPDATE: Here is what I said to Radio New Zealand yesterday afternoon on immigration, in a reasonably extended interview, partly on Labour’s announcement, but mostly on the more general issues.