There was interesting long article in The Guardian the other day by Sebastian Mallaby, the author of a new biography of Alan Greenspan, on “The cult of the expert – and how it collapsed”. His focus is central banking, but his concerns range much wider. For Mallaby, the (alleged) “collapse” of this “cult” is something to lament.
Of course, when you are brought up the son of a former senior British ambassador, educated at Eton and Oxford, previously a columnist for the Financial Times and then the Washington Post, when you are married to the editor of The Economist, when your books are biographies of two prominent unelected figures – Greenspan and James Wolfensohn, former head of the World Bank – and when your column is published in The Guardian – house journal of the British left-liberal technocratic elite – such a lament might be seen as not much more than a piece of class advocacy.
But I’ve usually found Mallaby interesting, and this column – which is well worth reading – had me reflecting again on quite what I think experts should be for. To get ahead of myself (and pre-empt a long post), my answer was “advice” and “execution”, but only rarely for “decisions”. That is a quite different answer than the one Mallaby offers. For him, experts simply need to sharpen up their act, become a bit more politically savvy, and show that they deserve the power they have assumed.
Quite early in his article, Mallaby poses the question thus
No senator would have his child’s surgery performed by an amateur. So why would he not entrust experts with the economy?
That one seemed pretty straightforward to me. When one of my kids needed surgery a few years ago, I wanted expert advice on the options, risks and implications, and I wanted an expert carrying out the surgery, but the decision to proceed with one option rather than another wasn’t the surgeon’s. It was mine. The doctor has some specialized knowledge and technical skills, on the sort of case he had probably seen hundreds of times before (and I’d seen not at all). And if the doctor ended up doing a completely different procedure than the one I’d authorized, or botched the operation, I had specific remedies and complaints procedures I could follow. I’m sure there are complex cases, and sometimes genuine debate among medical professionals about the best way to treat some conditions, but ultimately the decision to proceed or not is made by the patient (or parent/guardian).
The same might go for house renovations. A good architect, and capable expert builders and other tradespeople, can together enable an outcome that I couldn’t deliver myself. Most of us need, and value, expert advice, and expert execution, but the decision to renovate the house, and how far to go, is the customer’s. It is about choices and preferences on the one hand, and advice from experts who actually usually know what they are doing on the other.
It isn’t clear to me that there are very many areas of public policy where arrangements should be much different.
There are plenty of areas where in the administration of policy we don’t want politicians to have a hands-on role. It is one of the cornerstones of our system that rules and laws, once established, should be applied impartially, without fear or favour. Whether it is Supreme Court judges interpreting and applying the laws, or clerks administering benefit eligibility rules in WINZ, we don’t want politicians – or any other of the “powerful” – getting a better deal, and more favoured treatment, than anyone else. It is an ideal, and it isn’t always perfectly realized, but it is an ideal that is important to keep before us in designing and monitoring systems. But it isn’t mostly an issue about technical expertise, but about impartiality in deciding on the administration of the rules.
Setting the rules themselves is quite a different matter. That is, in many respects, the essence of politics and political debate – hard choices, conflicting interests, conflicting evidence, and sometimes conflicting values.
As Mallaby notes, central bank operational independence, especially around monetary policy, became something of a stalking horse for people with interests in many other fields of policy.
The key to the power of the central bankers – and the envy of all the other experts – lay precisely in their ability to escape political interference. Democratically elected leaders had given them a mission – to vanquish inflation – and then let them get on with it. To public-health experts, climate scientists and other members of the knowledge elite, this was the model of how things should be done. Experts had built Microsoft. Experts were sequencing the genome. Experts were laying fibre-optic cable beneath the great oceans.
He draws on the published thoughts of Alan Blinder, Princeton economist, who spent time as chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers, and as vice-chairman of the Federal Reserve. As Mallaby tells it:
His argument reflected the contrast between his two jobs in Washington. At the White House, he had advised a brainy president on budget policy and much else, but turning policy wisdom into law had often proved impossible. Even when experts from both parties agreed what should be done, vested interests in Congress conspired to frustrate enlightened progress. At the Fed, by contrast, experts were gloriously empowered. They could debate the minutiae of the economy among themselves, then manoeuvre the growth rate this way or that, without deferring to anyone.
To Blinder, it was self-evident that the Fed model was superior – not only for the experts, but also in the eyes of the public.
…..Blinder advanced an alternative idea: the central-bank model of expert empowerment should be extended to other spheres of governance.
Blinder’s proposal was most clearly illustrated by tax policy. Experts from both political parties agreed that the tax system should be stripped of perverse incentives and loopholes. There was no compelling reason, for example, to encourage companies to finance themselves with debt rather than equity, yet the tax code allowed companies to make interest payments to their creditors tax-free, whereas dividend payments to shareholders were taxed twice over. The nation would be better off if Congress left the experts to fix such glitches rather than allowing politics to frustrate progress. Likewise, environmental targets, which balanced economic growth on the one hand and planetary preservation on the other, were surely best left to the scholars who understood how best to reconcile these duelling imperatives. Politicians who spent more of their time dialing for dollars than thinking carefully about policy were not up to these tasks. Better to hand them off to the technicians in white coats who knew what they were doing.
And yet, 20 years on, there is no sign that the public – really anywhere in the advanced western world – wants to hand more policy-setting power over to technocrats and unelected officials. (On other hand, the power grab by officials – and even ministers averse to the involvement of legislatures – goes on in almost every country; the administrative state keeps growing.)
The Reserve Bank of New Zealand Act gets a brief mention in Mallaby’s article. In conception, it was perhaps the strongest possible case for delegating operational policy decision to officials (“experts” – although none of the three decision-making Governors since 1989 would really have qualified as monetary policy experts when they were appointed). It seems to me that three or four beliefs/propositions underpinned the case for handing over decision-making power around the conduct of monetary policy:
- politicians had all the wrong incentives and would almost invariably postpone hard decisions, creating a bias towards inflation, and excessive economic variability,
- it was relatively straightforward to specify the goal society wanted pursued with monetary policy (so officials weren’t being asked to make meaningful trade-offs, just “read the data, and do the right thing – the latter according to the societal rule”)
- it was relatively straightforward for able technocrats to make the right decision – consistent with the societal rule.
- holding officials to account was quite straightforward.
There is a small element of caricature in the way I’ve written that list, but I think it gets at the essential assumptions behind the monetary policy bits of the Reserve Bank Act.
Perhaps it was a reasonable story for ministers and officials to tell themselves in the early post-liberalization years. But none of it bears much relationship to reality.
Perhaps politicians postpone hard decisions on monetary policy – though it has never been clear to me why this should have been more of a problems in respect of monetary policy (where the lags are quite short) than in other areas of public life (where the lags are often long, and adverse consequences hard to pin down even years later). And, of course, we’ve now spent the best part of decade grappling with inflation rather lower than most official targets suggest desirable.
And people pretty quickly realized that technical experts could disagree – at times quite vociferously – and that there was no very obvious reason to consistently favour one technical expert over another. And there were/are real choices being made – on things that matter to voters, such as how much to prioritise lingering unemployment gaps, and on things where it isn’t easy for society to write down in advance how it wants to technical experts to manage the tensions and trade-offs. And there is no reason to think that “technical experts” are any better placed to decide those trade-offs (or less prone to be influenced by their own class or educational interests/biases) than the public as a whole through the political process.
And, largely as a result, effective accountability for central bankers is limited at best – really only at the time of potential reappointment. There are no complaints procedures or expert review and investigatory bodies. And while the New Zealand case isn’t general, in our case not only is the power handed over to an unelected agency – notionally ‘expert’ – but it has been handed over to a single individual for many years at a time. That isn’t done in other areas of public policy, even when policymaking powers have been delegated by Parliament.
A fundamental part of any proposal to delegating policymaking power to “experts” has to be that such “experts” really know what they are doing. But the evidence for that, even as regards monetary policy is now pretty slender. I certainly wouldn’t be hiring as builder or a surgeon someone who had as bad a track record as the world’s central bankers have had over the last decade or so. That isn’t intended as a personal criticism of any of them, all of whom have no doubt sought to do their best. But they’ve constantly misjudged inflation pressures, and not randomly but systematically. I’m not even suggesting replacing them with another bunch of superior experts. It is just that the limitations of our knowledge are simply too great. Even if we could all agree that the only thing we wanted from our central banks, year in year out, was 2 per cent inflation, there is no expert consensus on how best to deliver it, and what expert consensus there is has a pretty poor track record.
And, of course, there is even less agreement in practice – where society seems not just to want 2 per cent inflation, year in year out. In the current climate, some favour a more aggressive use of monetary policy, perhaps to use demand to soak up laid aside labour and prompt a resurgence in the supply side of the economy (Janet Yellen’s recent speech seemed to point a bit in that direction). Others are quite content to put inflation targets somewhat on the backburner for a while, out of fear of incipient financial crises (in this part of world, both Graeme Wheeler and Phil Lowe) seem inclined to that sort of thinking. In Sweden not long ago the monetary policy decision-making body was torn apart by the tension between these sorts of views. There is no straightforward generally agreed analytical framework, revealed only to the “experts”, enabling them to make such decisions better than anyone else.
Thus, I was bit troubled when I read Phil Lowe’s first speech as Governor. In it he notes some of these choices and trade-offs, but then falls back on the (non-statutory) concept of “the public interest” (the RBA’s statutory goals are much vaguer than those of the RBNZ, but “the public interest” doesn’t feature, at least not directly).
He notes
So when thinking about what type of variation in inflation is acceptable, it is natural for us to start by asking ourselves: what is in the public interest?
But
Granted, this can be hard to define and opinions can differ
And
This might all be less tightly defined than some people would like. But given the uncertainties in the world, something more prescriptive and mechanical is neither possible nor desirable. Inevitably, judgement has to be exercised. Successive governments have appointed nine dedicated Australians to the Reserve Bank Board to exercise that judgement in the public interest.
I have a lot of sympathy for the view that a “more prescriptive and mechanical” target for discretionary monetary policy isn’t really possible. But if it isn’t possible, why should suppose that Lowe, his deputy, the Secretary to the Treasury, and the non-executive directors – not one of whom ever faces an electoral test – are best placed to work out what is in “the public interest”? Better than the (somewhat dysfunctional) elected governments? If there is going to be an operationally independent central bank, I think the Australian governance model is clearly superior to our own (though in turn probably inferior to the UK’s) but why would one delegate such discretionary powers at all? One could no doubt mount an argument for lower, or higher, interest rates in Australia at present, even with a shared assessment of the outlook for inflation. The differences will turn on preferences, values and – frankly – hunches. They won’t turn on, say, the sort of solid track record of a surgeon who has done much the same operation hundreds of times before. None of us – central bankers, outside economists, politicians, the public – have ever seen quite such conjunctions of economic circumstances before.
None of which is some call for rank populism. As I said very early on in this post, there is a valuable role for experts in advice and execution. We want capable people who know exactly what they are doing conducting the market operations that implement monetary policy. And it is likely that economists and related experts can offer some useful advice on the options that societies face around monetary policy and the underperformance of economies in recent years. But the “experts” just don’t know that much at present – that isn’t an accusation, it is a fairly neutral description of what one reads in speech after central bank speech. And it isn’t a matter of shame, but of alignment. We shouldn’t – and generally don’t – delegate policy decisions when the evidence base is weak and there are real and contested tradeoffs.
And all this has been about monetary policy, where perhaps once the case for delegation looked strongest. Banking regulation is perhaps a clearer illustration of my point: we want people administering the rules without fear or favour, we need detailed expertise on specific instruments or institutions, and we need expert advice as input to policymaking. But in setting policy there are real and inescapable choices, and there is little obvious reason to think decision-making on what the rules should be should be delegated to “experts”. Take LVR policy as a recent New Zealand example: all the choices have distributional implications, there is little or no established body of knowledge of research, and in the end the decisions that have been made rest on little more than educated hunches, and about risks, costs and tradeoffs. Perhaps they are the right hunches, but we have no way of knowing. It isn’t remotely like asking a doctor to use his expertise to reset a broken bone. If the case for such policy is so strong, let the experts persuade the politicians – who are elected, and can be unelected.
Mallaby is writing with two backdrops in mind. The first is his recent biography of Greenspan, who appears as a hero in the story. And the second is what he appears to regard as the “disaster” of Brexit and the Trump insurgency (even if the latter now appears unlikely to storm the citadel). About Greenspan, you can read Mallaby’s argument for yourself. I’m more inclined to the view, reflected in Peter Conti-Brown’s book that I wrote about earlier in the year, that Alan Greenspan is an argument for term limits for heads of central banks. Over 19 years as head of the Federal Reserve he became such a dominant presence, including in the political debate, that (among other things) his views somewhat overshadowed the looming risks that eventually culminated in the 2008/09 crisis. And frankly, no matter how able – and Greenspan didn’t walk on water – there is something amiss when a technocrat, never facing an election, wields that much power.
I was (and am) a Brexit supporter, so I can’t share Mallaby’s distaste for Michael Gove’s dismissal of “experts” in that debate. How one’s country should be governed, in close association with which other countries, seem quintessentially like an issue on which the public might quite reasonably have a view. To be sure, as always, there is a place for expert advice on the issues and implications of the various possible choices, but “experts” have interests too, and they are necessarily or always those of the wider public. As I noted earlier in the year, in many cases the end of the British empire led to independent successor states that struggled economically. Perhaps independence was a “sensible economic choice”, but in sense that is the point; people value different things, and perhaps put a premium in that case on self-government, even if at some economic cost.
Towards the end of his article, Mallaby notes
Democracy is strengthened, not weakened, when it harnesses experts.
And I agree. But the operative word there is “harnessed”. Experts have a valuable role as advisers and – in policy matters often a different set of “experts” – as implementers. Expert advice can help illuminate the costs and consequences of the choices and tradeoffs societies make – whether relatively mundane ones around monetary policy, or more existential ones around decisions to go to war, to construct welfare states or whatever – but “experts” are typically ill-equipped to make those decisions for us. In fact, often enough, even what appears to be a consensus of expert opinion – or establishment opinion (often the same thing) – is left in tatters by experience. To end on a note more of politics than economics, there was a column in the New York Times a few days ago
Almost every crisis that has come upon the West in the last 15 years has its roots in this establishmentarian type of folly. The Iraq War, which liberals prefer to remember as a conflict conjured by a neoconservative cabal, was actually the work of a bipartisan interventionist consensus, pushed hard by George W. Bush but embraced as well by a large slice of center-left opinion that included Tony Blair and more than half of Senate Democrats.
Likewise the financial crisis: Whether you blame financial-services deregulation or happy-go-lucky housing policy (or both), the policies that helped inflate and pop the bubble were embraced by both wings of the political establishment. Likewise with the euro, the European common currency, a terrible idea that only cranks and Little Englanders dared oppose until the Great Recession exposed it as a potentially economy-sinking folly.
Like most cults, the “cult of the expert” is more dangerous than Mallaby – or most of the expert class – acknowledges. And hotly contested political debate, messy as it often, wrong directions that it sometimes takes, are how we make the hard choices, the trade-offs, amid the inevitable uncertainty. Abandoning that model is akin to gutting our democracy of much of its substance. So I still want an expert operating on my child, but I want parliaments making laws and setting taxes (not officials) and parliaments taking us to war (not generals). And I increasingly wonder whether monetary policy decisions should be left to officials either – no matter how technically able, and how many of them on the decisionmaking panel.
The big problem for we lay people lies in determining whether or not a person who holds himself out as an expert really is an expert.
For example, how do we know that a person who is held out by his employer as an expert on banking, and who actually earns much of his living from being an Associate Professor at the School of Economics & Finance at a New Zealand university, really is an expert on banking?
Well, the answer to that is that we know he’s not an expert at all, because he wrote a piece for an encyclopaedia describing the operations of banks according to the ‘loanable funds’ model which was totally discredited way back in 1956 by the NZ Royal Commission on Banking, Monetary, and Credit Systems, and again in papers published by the Bank of England — “Money creation in the modern economy” in 2014 (www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/documents/quarterlybulletin/2014/qb14q1prereleasemoneycreation.pdf) and “Banks are not intermediaries of loanable funds — and why this matters”, in 2015 (www.bankofengland.co.uk/research/Documents/workingpapers/2015/wp529.pdf).
This so-called ‘expert’ wrote the Banking and Finance section of the Encyclopaedia of New Zealand – Te Ara. Here are some excerpts from it:
“Intermediation
Banks have a role as financial intermediaries because they specialise in assessing the creditworthiness of borrowers, who will not be known to depositors. The depositor entrusts their money to the bank with the expectation that the bank will ensure that the value of loans backing the deposit, and therefore the bank’s ability to repay, is maintained.”
“Balance of risk
Banks and other financial institutions are an important source of liquidity (spending power) for an economy, since deposits held for transaction purposes must be available for transfer on demand. A substantial proportion of bank deposits are held in on-demand or readily accessible accounts. On the other hand, borrowers generally need longer-term funding. Banks reconcile these competing needs by assuming that not all customers holding demand deposits will withdraw or spend them at the same time.”
“Bank revenue
Customers deposit funds (savings) with banks, and banks generally pay interest on savings. Banks then lend that money to people who want to borrow. They charge the borrowers a higher interest rate, generating some net interest income. Banks also gain income from fees and from providing other services.
Out of their gross income they pay their operating expenses such as staff, premises and the technology that powers the payments system, write off any losses on loans (from borrowers who have been unable to repay them), and pay tax. At the end of this process they are left with a net profit after tax”
It should be perfectly clear to any intelligent reader that the above three excerpts are contradicted by the aforementioned Bank of England paper, in that banks are money creators. They do not lend out their deposits and are therefore not financial intermediaries.
The reason that so-called ‘experts’ in economics are so deluded in their understanding of what banks do is that almost all secondary schools and universities teach this part of macroeconomics incorrectly. The people at The University of Auckland, my alma mater, believe that ‘academic freedom’ gives them the right to teach whatever they like, however they like. I have challenged them on this, as it flies in the face of the very strict constraints to academic freedom, framed by parliament, that are set out in the Education Act 1989, and having received their refusal to do anything to correct what they teach, I laid a formal complaint with the Ministry of Education, which eventually gave me a nonsense reply.
Undeterred, I wrote to the Minister of Education, who referred my letter to the Minister for Tertiary Education. He completely failed to grasp the point, and responded by writing “I am satisfied that the University of Auckland is acting within the ambit of the autonomy prescribed to it in the Education Act.”
Here is the relevant excerpt from the Education Act 1989:
“161 Academic freedom
(1) It is declared to be the intention of parliament in enacting the provisions of this Act relating to institutions that academic freedom and the autonomy of institutions are to be preserved and enhanced.
(2) For the purposes of this section, academic freedom, in relation to an institution, means—
(a) the freedom of academic staff and students, within the law, to question and test received wisdom, to put forward new ideas and to state controversial or unpopular opinions:
(b) the freedom of academic staff and students to engage in research:
(c) the freedom of the institution and its staff to regulate the subject matter of courses taught at the institution:
(d) the freedom of the institution and its staff to teach and assess students in the manner they consider best promotes learning:
(e) the freedom of the institution through its chief executive to appoint its own staff.
(3) In exercising their academic freedom and autonomy, institutions shall act in a manner that is consistent with—
(a) the need for the maintenance by institutions of the highest ethical standards and the need to permit public scrutiny to ensure the maintenance of those standards;
and
(b) the need for accountability by institutions and the proper use by institutions of resources allocated to them.
(4) In the performance of their functions the Councils and chief executives of institutions, Ministers, and authorities and agencies of the Crown shall act in all respects so as to give effect to the intention of Parliament as expressed in this section.
Section 161: inserted, on 23 July 1990, by section 36 of the Education Amendment Act 1990 (1990 No. 60).”
So there we have it in black and white. Parliament did not give academics academic freedom carte blanche, but imposed quite severe constraints on it.
I feel quite justified in stating that Steven Joyce, Minister of Tertiary Education, is definitely not an expert on interpreting the Education Act 1989!
LikeLike
As (almost) ever, an interesting discussion – thank you. Incidentally, Sebastian’s father, Sir George Mallaby, was the British High Commissioner to NZ 1957-1960. His memoirs (From My Level. Unwritten Minutes. (1965) London: Hutchinson & Co) contain vivid word pictures of the three NZ Prime Ministers with whom he dealt: Sydney Holland, Keith Holyoake, and Walter Nash, as well as Lord Cobham the Governor General.
LikeLiked by 1 person
different mallaby I think (https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Sebastian_Mallaby) – perhaps one more generation back? I’ve read Sir George Mallaby’s book and quite enjoyed it – esp as Holland is a relative of mine.
UPDATE: It seems that Sir George Mallaby (High Commissioner) only had step-children https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/George_Mallaby_(public_servant)
LikeLiked by 1 person
Be good to hear an expert or political leader describe how to retain the benefits of a market based system (e.g. innovation etc.) but outline the way in which serving sizes could become less uneven in the future without denting the incentive to growth the economic pie. A difficult task…?
LikeLike
I don’t claim any great expertise in that area, but fixing the housing market would be a huge step forward. Freeing up land use regulations and cutting back immigration together could do that quite quickly (land use liberalization alone could do it too, if far-reaching enough).
LikeLike
Dear Michael,
You are a superb wordsmith with a worldwide following, but one rule you still need to learn: read the first line one more time before you push the magic button! In this world of glitz and glamour, you can’t afford a typo in your opener! You just can’t!
Best regards
Paul MB
LikeLike
Thanks Paul. I assume you mean export/expert. I must have read it at least three times before I finally spotted it. I cringed…..
LikeLike
In the U.K. between 1993 and 1997, the Chancellor of the Exchequer (Ken Clarke) set interest rates, with the aim of achieving an inflation target established by the Government after Black Wednesday and with transparent advice from the Governor of the Bank of England (Eddie George). This included published minutes of their meetings, so it was clear when the Chancellor had or had not taken the Governor’s advice. The arrangement was known as the ‘Ken and Eddie Show’ and is described in more detail in this article in the Independent when it was clear that the Labour Party was planning to replace it. Maybe this provides a possible model for ‘harnessing experts.’
http://www.independent.co.uk/news/what-comes-after-the-ken-and-eddie-show-1278965.html
LikeLike
Yes, I think that “Ken and Eddie” show was a quite workable sort of model. I’m not sure I’m quite yet persuaded that operational autonomy should permanently be removed from central banks, but (a) the case at present seems particularly weak, and (b) the UK is a good example of a country that both got inflation down (under Thatcher) with an advisory/implementer central bank, and then sustained it for some years with an advisory/implementer central bank (under Ken and Eddie).
More generally, inflation in the 1950s was pretty low across a whole bunch of countries with non-independent central banks.
LikeLike