Monetary policy, expectations etc

I’ve been reading a few books lately on aspects of monetary policy, and might come back to write about some or all of them. But there has been quite a bit of discussion recently – on economics Twitter, and blogs – about a new working paper from a senior Federal Reserve researcher, Jeremy Rudd.

Judd’s paper runs under the title “Why Do We Think That Inflation Expectations Matter for Inflation? (And Should We?)”, which seems like a worthwhile question, especially at the moment when – and especially in the US – debates rages as to how just how transitory (or otherwise) the recent surge in inflation rates will prove. It is common to hear central bankers opining about how much may turn on whether these higher headline rates get into (alter, affect) the expectations about future inflation of firms and households.

If you come at these things from a New Zealand perspective, the most remarkable thing about the paper is probably that it was published at all. How well I recall getting rapped over the knuckles, with severe expressions of disapproval from Alan Bollard, when I used a quiet New Year’s Eve in the office a decade ago to write a short discussion note, circulated in that form only among a dozen or so senior colleagues, in which I had the temerity to suggest that we might consider advancing the case for a legislated Monetary Policy Committee. Not exactly radical stuff, given that it was the way most countries did things (and NZ now does things). When somewhat later word of the paper got out – a Treasury official who had a copy mentioned it in a reference in a paper that was OIAed – the Bank insisted on fighting all the way to the Ombudsman (where the Bank won) to prevent release. Sceptical perspectives on LVR restrictions, before they were put in place, were equally unwelcome, even internally. And when I say “unwelcome”, I don’t mean anything of the sort of “interesting arguments, but I’m not persuaded because of x, y, and z”, but much more of a “back in your box” sort of thing.

And both of those examples are just about internal circulation. I’m pretty sure that no Reserve Bank analyst, economist, researcher or the like has ever published anything that made the hierarchy even slightly uncomfortable in the entire 31.5 year history of the modern (operationally autonomous) Bank. Consistent with that, of course, even though we now have a Monetary Policy Committee with non-executive members, it operates totally under the thumb of the Governor and nothing of a diversity of view is ever heard. The contrast to, say, the Bank of England, Sweden’s Riksbank, or the Federal Reserve is stark.

I don’t want to appear all starry-eyed and naive here. Every institution – every central bank – has its limits, and even the more-open places seem to be quite a bit more open than they were. But it is inconceivable that anything like Rudd’s paper could have been published by the Reserve Bank, even though in many respects it is much less radical than some commentary has tried to suggest, or than the tone Rudd affects on page 1, with his

Economics is replete with ideas that “everyone knows” to be true, but that are actually arrant nonsense.

And

One natural source of concern is if dubious but widely held ideas serve as the basis for consequential policy decisions.2

I have no idea of Mr Rudd’s politics, but like many readers I was intrigued by the footnote to that sentence

2  I leave aside the deeper concern that the primary role of mainstream economics in our society is to provide an apologetics for a criminally oppressive, unsustainable, and unjust social order.

To be honest, I used to edit Reserve Bank research and analytical papers etc for publications and – keen on openness and diversity as I am (see above) – I’d have insisted that sentence come out. Attention-grabbing but quite unrelated to the substance of the paper (or the functions of the Bank) would no doubt have been the gist of my comment.

But what of the substance of the paper? There isn’t really much there that is new. Quite a bit of it is about the limitations of how formal macroeconomic models capture, and ground, a role for inflation expectations. I don’t think any of that will have surprised most readers, or disconcerted anyone who has been associated with the actual conduct of monetary policy in recent decades. Perhaps you might be slightly disconcerted by his point that the models often seem to put more weight on short-term expectations (where surprises/shocks can generate real consequences) but that “one of the few shreds of empirical evidence that we do have suggests that it is long-run expectations that are more relevant for inflation dynamics”.

But even then I’m not sure that you should be disconcerted, in part because nowhere in the entire paper are interest rates mentioned, or financial instruments, and I (at least) have always thought of the role of inflation expectations as potentially most important in the context of a willingness to borrow (in particular) given the prevalence still of long-term nominal debt contracts (particularly so in countries such as the US where long-term fixed rate debt is a large chunk of the market). A 5 per cent mortgage rate is one thing if I’m working with an implicit, perhaps even unconscious, sense that normal inflation is 5 per cent, and quite another if I’m working with 0 per cent inflation as my norm.

There is a school of thought (class of economic rhetoriticians) who will assert, sometimes quite strongly, that in the long-run inflation expectations are the only determinant of inflation. I had a boss for some years who regularly ran that line. And, to be sure, you can set up a model in which it is true, but that model typically won’t be very enlightening at all, since “inflation expectations” (however conceived or measured, and measurement is a real challenge) don’t occur in a vacuum. If we had the data in the early 1980s, New Zealand inflation expectations might well have been about 12 per cent (say), but inflation expectations were that high because of some mix of (a) the government and the Reserve Bank not having done much to get inflation any lower, and (b) the government and the Reserve Bank not being thought likely to do much in future to get inflation much lower. Policy tended to validate the expectations, but it wasn’t the expectations that determined inflation, but the policy itself. When policy stopped validating those high expectations, they came down (albeit often quite slowly, sensibly enough (on the part of those forming the expectations).

Those misperceptions can matter. When we were trying to get inflation down (to something centred on 1 per cent) in the late 80s and early 90s, no one put much weight on the chances of success. Quite probably many of us didn’t either (I recall a conversation with the-then Westpac chief economist in which I suggested that I’d be reluctant to bet on inflation averaging below 3 per cent for the following 20-30 years). That made it harder (and costlier) to get actual inflation down, but – through some mix of good luck, bureaucratic resolution, and close-run-thing political commitment – we did. And indications of expectations about future inflation followed. A 14 per cent bank bill rate by the mid 1990s no longer meant what it had in 1988, when the inflation targeting scheme was first hatched.

On the other hand, it seems likely (but I’m more open on this) that during the period over the last decade when core inflation was persistently low – repeatedly surprising the Reserve Bank, among others – the fact that indicators of inflation expectations mostly tended to hold up nearer the target midpoint may have helped, a little, avoid more of a fall in inflation itself (although even this is arguable since had inflation expectations fallen away more sharply and obviously, the Reserve Bank might well have used policy more aggressively than it did, including getting unemployment down earlier/further).

One of the other limitations of Rudd’s paper is that there is barely any mention of any country’s experience other than that of the United States. Of course, he is American, writing in an American institution for a primary audience that is America, but…..data. In truth, there just is not that much data in any individual country (because no matter how many series and how high-frequency the data, there are only so many genuine cyclical episodes to study). In almost no other country in the world is it conceivable that someone would write such a paper without looking beyond their own borders, and own central bank. Even for the US, it should be more important, since the Fed focused on an index which doesn’t have a great deal of general public visibility, whereas many other inflation targeters will at least start from the CPI.

For me – as someone with (mostly) a policy focus – the most significant part of Rudd’s paper was the last few pages on “Possible practical implications” and “Possible policy implications”. I had a tick beside this paragraph

Another practical implication is rhetorical. By telling policymakers that expected inflation is the ultimate determinant of inflation’s long-run trend, central-bank economists implicitly provide too much assurance that this claim is settled fact. Advice along these lines also naturally biases policymakers toward being overly concerned with expectations management, or toward concluding that survey- or market-based measures of expected inflation provide useful and reliable policy guideposts. And in some cases, the illusion of control is arguably more likely to cause problems than an actual lack of control.

But for all the glib rhetoric that sometimes comes from senior central bankers, I wonder how many – if any – practical central bankers operate as if they really believe that everything (about future inflation) rests on inflation expectations. I’ve had many criticisms of the Reserve Bank of New Zealand over the years, but not even Don Brash acted and operated policy as if that was his view, and certainly none of his successors have.

Perhaps more interesting was this

Related to this last point, an important policy implication would be that it is far more useful to
ensure that inflation remains off of people’s radar screens than it would be to attempt to “re-anchor” expected inflation at some level that policymakers viewed as being more consistent with
their stated inflation goal. In particular, a policy of engineering a rate of price inflation that is
high relative to recent experience in order to effect an increase in trend inflation would seem to
run the risk of being both dangerous and counterproductive inasmuch as it might increase the
probability that people would start to pay more attention to inflation and—if successful—would
lead to a period where trend inflation once again began to respond to changes in economic
conditions.

It harks back a bit to the definition of price stability Alan Greenspan once used to give, that it is when inflation isn’t a consideration for people (firms and households) in the ordinary course of their lives, but also seems to be a bit of dig at the current FOMC policy of aiming to run core inflation above target for a time. I’m probably more sympathetic to that approach than Rudd – including for New Zealand after a decade of undershooting the target – but his comment is a perspective that should be taken seriously.

HIs final main point is this

A related issue is more pragmatic. In some ways, the situation that arises from a focus on
long-term inflation expectations is similar to one in which a policymaker seeks to target a single
indicator of full employment—for instance, the natural rate of unemployment. Like the natural
rate, the long-run expectations that are relevant for wage and price determination cannot be directly measured, but instead need to be inferred from empirical models. Hence, using inflation
expectations as a policy instrument or intermediate target has the result of adding a new unobservable to the mix. And, as Orphanides (2004) has persuasively argued, policies that rely too
heavily on unobservables can often end in tears.

People (including central bankers) fool themselves if they think that survey responses, or implied breakevens from inflation-indexed bond markets, “are” inflation expectations (for the economy as a whole) themselves. They are what they are, and always have to be taken with at least some pinches of salt. In New Zealand, for example, household surveys regularly produce numbers suggesting households expect to average between 3 and 5 per cent over periods 1 to 5 years ahead, but no one has ever taken those absolute numbers seriously (there is little or nothing else anywhere in the economy suggesting that whatever people tell surveytakers they act as if they think inflation will be this high). At best, they are indicators, straws in the wind, and sometimes what look like good relationships then no longer do.

As an example of the latter, the Reserve Bank economics department at times articulated a line that the two-year ahead measure of inflation expectations in the Bank’s survey of informed observers) almost was a measure of core inflation itself.

expecs and core inflation

It held up quite well over the best part of 15 years, until it didn’t. It left the Bank too complacent through the following decade (but the error could equally have run the other way).

I guess my bottom line is that one should rarely put too much weight on any specific indicator, and perhaps especially ones that are hard to observe (or to know what one observes actually means). If we see medium-term inflation expectations – among informed observers – at 5 per cent, we (and central bankers) should be disconcerted, but it is highly unlikely that such an inflation expectations number will have been the first sign of trouble.

Changing tack, what of current monetary policy in New Zealand? There is an OCR review tomorrow. Expectations measures here don’t appear troublesome at all – even the inflation breakevens are getting nearer the target midpoint than we’ve known for some years. But core inflation has been rising, unemployment had fallen quite low, and a lot of indicators pointed to emerging capacity pressures. All that was, of course, before the latest Covid outbreak.

I still think there is a very good case for things the Reserve Bank MPC will not do tomorrow: discontinue the Funding for Lending programme, and start a well-signalled programme of bond sales to reverse the LSAP programme. But what of the OCR itself? I won’t be particularly critical of the MPC if they do raise the OCR by 25 basis points tomorrow, but I think if I was in their shoes I wouldn’t. There is a full forecast round and full MPS at the next review and a lot of uncertainty about the Covid outbreak and is its implications (as well as some emerging downside global risks, notably from China). Yes, monetary policy works with a lag, but the starting point for (core) inflation is not so high that we need to be in a hurry to raise the OCR in such an uncertain and unsettled climate. We will know a great deal more – including about vaccinations, and hopefully about exit pathways – on 24 November than we do now. If all is going really well by then, or if core inflation in the CPI later this month is really troubling, there need be no problem with going 50 basis points then, if the data support such a call. But I wouldn’t be rushing right now.

12 thoughts on “Monetary policy, expectations etc

  1. Stagflation surprising – with inflation rising eventually to 5%?

    Who could have forecast that QE could generate wild asset inflation, and push up consumer prices to boot?

    My money would bet that the savers get slapped, and the borrowers get bailed…

    I’m sure I saw this flick before. An oldie but a goodie. In fact, this may now be a franchise.

    Episode one followed 911, and the sequel came during and after the financial crisis in 2008…

    Like The Empire Strikes Back, the sequel was better than the original…

    The third episode could be titled “Revenge of the Orr”?

    Like

    • The recession from 2008 had nothing to do with the GFC. The 2008 to 2010 recession was engineered by Allan Bollard and the RBNZ driving interest rates to 15% in the business sector and in the building and development sector. The RBNZ was stupidly focussed on longer term residential fixed interest rates at 7% and getting frustrated that they could not affect longer term rates and forgot that businesses were crashing at 15% interest rates. Blind as bats.

      Like

  2. Actually the OCR rise today is too little too late.
    Inflation is here again,and as probably justifiable ,the Unions have noted that , Plus full employment and sympathetic governance,the time is right to achieve compensation or better.Next—, wage prices spiral.
    NZ needs to belt up for another rocky ride

    Like

    • Note to provoke a long debate, but the day before the lockdown I’d have agreed with you, and had the lockdown quickly eliminated Covid again I’d have agreed then. But there is rampant uncertainty now, which is likely to affect willingness to spend and invest.

      Like

  3. I agree with your thoughts on cancelling the FFL programme and a planned reversing of the LSAP purchases. That would have a more significant impact on longer term rates and provide better signalling about longer term inflation concerns.

    Like

    • The $28b FFL programme or FLP is clearly a negotiated part of enabling the purchase of $59b of Treasury Bonds. RBNZ has confirmed a binding gentleman’s agreement. However the drawdown to date by banks is only $5b. It does suggest that the use of the FLP is likely very narrowly restrictive. But no point harping on about shutting it down as it is likely created as an offset facility.

      The Crown has to issue new 30 year bonds of up to $28b or $23b less the $5b drawdown to enable the shut down of this facility. Don’t forget the RBNZ although has the unlimited ability to print money it did not. Instead the purchase of the bonds was completed by a IOU. Dr LSAP $59b Cr Bank Settlement deposit liability $59b. The Crown Settlement Account currently records $38b. This does suggest that the Crown had to issue new bonds to pay down the RBNZ IOU to banks but there remains $21b owing. This number is close enough to suggest that the FLP is an offset loan to RBNZ IOU to Banks via Banks Settlement deposit account..

      Like

      • Looking at the RBNZ Balance Sheet, there is actually no spare cash investments that the RB could actually advance the full $28b to Banks anyway. The Crown would have to issue new 30 year Bonds with an interest cost of 2.5% to enable the RBNZ to complete a full $28b drawdown earning interest of 0.25%. I think. the drawdown of $5b is as far as it gets. Once Crown Settlement account moves up to $59b from currently $38b would be when the RBNZ would announce the shutdown of the FLP. Therefore expect the Crown to issue a flurry of new 30 year bonds to clear up the remnants of the RBNZ LSAP bond buying.

        Like

  4. Further to The OCR,being roo little too late,
    Inflation expectations are rapidly increasing largely driven by energy prices and supply world wide
    Locally gas ,the huge increase in carbon price and supply.Add this to food etc and salary expectation NZ.
    Have seen predictions including “economic lag “ of inflation being about 7%.now.
    The RB should be doing its job!

    Like

  5. A bit late commenting on this thread but I thought “what the heck…”. I’d make two observations. The first is on actual inflation. It looks to me like the shock, which was very narrow to begin with, is broadening and we see that in the broad rise in food prices observed in rhe FPI on the last few months. We can also see it in the rental price index flow measure which absolutely exploded today. My projection for CPI is a lift of 1.6%q/q in Q3. I was very much in the camp that the shock was narrow, covid driven and core was stable, but my spreadsheets are telling me today that’s not entirely the case anymore.

    The second concerns inflation expectations. My good friend and new classical adherent from my time at the RBNZ, Richard, would tell me inflation expectations are forward looking but I think that’s not entirely true and given the long experience we have now with price stability, inflation expectations are likely to be fairly strongly autoregressive. Hence, a lift in inflation won’t necessarily be looked on as simply a one off shock, but may end up becoming sticky, leading to second round effects. The greater the autoregressiveness of expectations and the higher the sensitivity of inflation to expectations, the greater the risk of embedding higher inflation in the system.

    I don’t think we are quite in that world yet, but I’m increasingly of the view that the best course of action is to continue the policy of gradual stimulus withdrawal. It can be reversed if a shock hits such as a China property collapse, but its clear that the inflation genie is stirring for the first time in many years.

    Like

    • Thanks for those comments Peter. Largely agree with your final point. I wouldn’t have been unhappy if the Bank had been able to start raising the OCR in August, but – in their shoes – I probably still wouldn’t have made the first move in the middle of the extreme uncertainty the Bank faced earlier this month. It does look as tho by Nov we will have a bit more certainty about the domestic situation (by then the vacc rate should be high and the govt is clearly moving towards living with Covid – altho getting acceptance in the rest of country will be hard).

      Meanwhile, the CPI should be helpful, on if (and if so, how much) core inflation had moved higher pre-lockdown.

      Like

  6. Personally, my view is that the people at the RB should have done their job. Not reacting to stagflation is a dereliction of duty, There aren’t any excuses.

    Not directly on topic, but a metric I always review to determine a country’s prospects is the percentage of government spending relative to GDP.

    About 35% is optimal, in my view. Over 50% is typically ruinous in the long term, I would say.

    https://www.statista.com/statistics/436523/ratio-of-government-expenditure-to-gross-domestic-product-gdp-in-new-zealand/

    2017 – 35.6%
    2020 – 42.4%

    6.5% of GDP, or 20% bigger, in just 3 years!

    The forecasts are for future falls in this percentage, but I don’t believe them.

    If Labour wins the next election, I forecast government expenditure as a percentage of GDP in NZ will be over 50% by 2026.

    Watch the public and private debt rates continue to skyrocket as well.

    The NZ economy is in huge medium term trouble, in my view.

    Like

Leave a comment